Furious
Sheep
By
Dmitry Orlov
August 04,
2016 "Information
Clearing House"
- "Club
Orlov"
- In all my years of watching politics in the
US, never have I seen a presidential election
generate such overwhelmingly negative emotions.
Everyone hates Donald Trump, Hillary Clinton, or,
increasingly, both of them. This is creating a
severe psychological problem for many people: they
want to tell their friends and the world that
Clinton is mentally unstable and a crook, but they
are conflicted because they realize that by so doing
they would be supporting Trump. Or they want to tell
everyone what a vulgar, narcissistic, egotistical
blowhard Trump is, but they are conflicted because
they realize that by so doing they would be
supporting Clinton. Some are abandoning the
two-party duopoly in favor of minor parties, ready
to vote for Jill Stein the Green or Gary Johnson the
Libertarian, but are conflicted because voting for
Stein would take votes away from Clinton the crook
and thus support Trump the blowhard, while voting
for Johnson would take votes away from Trump the
blowhard and thus support Clinton the crook. There
is just no winning! Or is there?
There is a long list of arguments for voting
against either of the major candidates, some of
them seemingly valid. At the top of the list of the
seemingly valid ones are that Clinton is corrupt and
a warmonger, while Trump is inexperienced and
socially divisive. But there is hardly a single
valid reason to be found anywhere why someone would
want to vote for either them. Some have
argued that Trump is less likely to cause World War
III, because his instincts are those of a
businessman, and he is primarily interested in
making money, not war; but Clinton likes money just
as much as Trump—just look at her gigantic private
slush fund known as the Clinton Foundation! On the
other hand, perhaps Trump will like the idea of
peace only until the moment he is elected, at which
point it will be explained to him that the US empire
is an extortion racket, and that breaking legs
(a.k.a. war) is how it comes up with the ink. And
then he will like war just as much as Clinton does.
None of this makes it easy for a lover of liberty
and peace to vote for either one of them in good
conscience.
I heard Jill Stein say that people should be able to
vote their conscience. Yes, let's concede that
voting against your conscience is probably bad for
your soul, if not your pocketbook. But this makes it
sound as if the voting booth were a confessional
rather than what it is—an apparatus by which people
can assert their very limited political power. But
do you have any political power, or are American
elections just a game of manipulation in which you
lose no matter how you vote? A 2014 study,
“Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites,
Interest Groups, and Average Citizens” by Martin
Gilens and Benjamin I. Page conclusively showed
how the preferences of average citizens matter not a
whit, while those of moneyed elites and interest
groups certainly do. Thus, the question as to
whether you are the winner or the loser in the game
of US electoral politics is easily answered: if you
are a multibillionaire and a captain of industry,
then you might win; if you are an average citizen,
then the chances of you winning are precisely zero.
Given that you
are going to lose, how should you play? Should you
behave like a Furious Sheep, obeying all the signals
fed to you by the candidates, their organizations
and the political commentators in the mass media?
Should you do your part to hand the largest possible
victory to those who are manipulating the political
process to their advantage? Or should you withhold
cooperation to the largest extent possible and try
to unmask them and neutralize their efforts at
political manipulation?
Sure, there are some cheap thrills to be had for the
Furious Sheep—endorphins from jumping up and down
while waving mass-produced signs and shouting
slogans pre-approved by campaign committees. But if
you are the sort of person who likes to have an
independent thought now and again, what you are
probably looking for are three things:
• avoid psychological damage from having to observe
and participate in this absurd and degrading
spectacle;
• experience the delicious thrill of watching this
system fail and those behind it lose face; and
• regain some amount of faith in the possibility of
a future for your children and grandchildren that
might involve something actually resembling some
sort of democracy rather than a humiliating, sordid,
rigged game.
Before we can play, we have to understand what
variety of game this is in technical terms. There
are many different kinds of games: games of strength
(tug-of-war), games of skill (fencing) and games of
strategy (backgammon). This one is a game of
strength, fought using large bags of money, but it
can be turned into a game of strategy by the weaker
side, not to win but to deny victory to the other
side.
Most of us are brought up with the nice idea that
games should be fair. In a fair game both sides have
a chance at victory, and there is normally a winner
and a loser, or, failing that, a tie. But fair games
represent only a subset of games, while the rest—the
vast majority—are unfair. Here, we are talking about
a specific type of unfair game in which your side
always loses. But does that mean that the other side
must always win? Not at all! There are two possible
outcomes: “you lose—they win” and “you lose—they
lose.”
Now, if you, being neither a multibillionaire nor a
captain of industry, are facing the prospect of
spending the rest of your life on the losing side,
which outcome should you wish for? Of course, you
should want the other side to lose too! The reason:
if those on the other side start losing, then they
will abandon this game and resort to some other
means of securing an unfair victory. In the case of
the game of American electoral politics, this would
pierce the veil of faux-democracy, generating a
level of public outrage that might make the
restoration of real democracy at least theoretically
possible.
So, how do you change the outcome from “you
lose—they win” to “you lose—they lose”?
The first question to answer is whether you should
bother voting at all, and the answer is, Yes, you
should vote. If you don’t vote, then you abandon the
playing field to the Furious Sheep who, being most
easily manipulated, will hand an easy victory to the
other side. And so the remaining question is, How
should you vote to make the other side lose? This
should not be regarded as a matter of personal
choice; no need to concern yourself with who is the
“lesser evil,” or which candidate made which
meaningless promises. You will not be casting a vote
for someone; you will be casting a vote against the
entire process. Think of yourself as a soldier who
volunteered in defense of liberty: you will simply
be carrying out your orders. The charge has been
laid by someone else; your mission, should you wish
to accept it, is to light the fuse and walk away.
This should at once motivate you to go and vote and
make the voting process easy and stress-free. You
are going to show up, subvert the dominant paradigm,
and go watch the fireworks.
Next, you have
to understand the way the electoral game is played.
It is played with money—very large sums of
money—with votes being quite secondary. In
mathematical terms, money is the independent
variable and votes are the dependent variable, but
the relationship
between money and votes is nonlinear and
time-variant. In the opening round, the moneyed
interests throw huge sums of money at both of the
major parties—not because elections have to be, by
their nature, ridiculously expensive, but to erect
an insurmountable barrier to entry for average
citizens. But the final decision is made on a
relatively thin margin of victory, in order to make
the electoral process appear genuine rather than
staged, and to generate excitement. After all, if
the moneyed interests just threw all their money at
their favorite candidate, making that candidate’s
victory a foregone conclusion, that wouldn’t look
sufficiently democratic. And so they use large sums
to separate themselves from you the great unwashed,
but much smaller sums to tip the scales.
When calculating how to tip the scales, the
political experts employed by the moneyed interests
rely on information on party affiliation, polling
data and historical voting patterns. To change the
outcome from a “lose-win” to a “lose-lose,” you need
to invalidate all three of these:
• The proper choice of party affiliation is “none,”
which, for some bizarre reason, is commonly labeled
as “independent,” (and watch out for American
Independent Party, which is a minor right-wing party
in California that has successfully trolled people
into joining it by mistake). Be that as it may; let
the Furious Sheep call themselves the “dependent”
ones. In any case, the two major parties are dying,
and the number of non-party members is now almost
the same as the number of Democrats and Republicans
put together.
• When responding to a poll, the category you should
always opt for is “undecided,” up to and including
the moment when you walk into the voting booth. When
questioned about your stands on various issues, you
need to remember that the interest in your opinion
is disingenuous: your stand on issues matters not a
whit (see study above) except as part of an effort
to herd you, a Furious Sheep, into a particular
political paddock. Therefore, when talking to
pollsters, be vaguely on both sides of every issue
while stressing that it plays no role in your
decision-making. Should you be asked what does
matter to you, concentrate on such issues as the
candidates’ body language, fashion sense and
demeanor. Doing so will effectively short-circuit
any attempt to manipulate you using your purely
fictional ability to influence public policy. You
cannot be for or against a candidate being
forthright and well-spoken; nor is there a litmus
test for comportment or fashion sense. Politicians
are supposed to be able to herd Furious Sheep by
making promises they have no intention of keeping.
But what if the voters (wise to the fact that their
opinions no longer matter) suddenly start demanding
better posture, more graceful hand gestures, a more
melodious tone of voice and a sprightlier step?
Calamity! What was supposed to be a fake but tidy
ideological battleground with fictional but clearly
delineated front lines suddenly turns into a macabre
beauty pageant held on a uniform field of liquefied
mud.
• The final step is to invalidate historical voting
patterns. Here, the perfectly obvious solution is to
vote randomly. Random voting will
produce not random but chaotic results, invalidating
the notion that the electoral process is about party
platforms, policies, issues or popular mandates.
More importantly, it will invalidate the process by
which votes are purchased, in effect getting money
out of politics. You just have to remember to bring
a penny into the voting booth with you. Here is a
flowchart that explains how you should decide who to
vote for once you are standing in the voting booth
holding a penny:
If you want to be an activist, bring a pocketful of
pennies and hand them out to people while standing
in line at the polling place. You won't need to
convince that many people to produce the intended
effect. Remember, in order to maintain the
appearance of a democratic process, the artificial,
financially induced margin of victory is kept quite
thin, and even a small amount of added randomness is
enough to wipe it out. Point out the word “liberty”
prominently embossed on each penny. Briefly explain
what a Furious Sheep is, and how the exercise of
liberty is the exact opposite of being a Furious
Sheep. Then explain to them how the pennies are to
be used: the first flip of the penny determines
whether you are voting for the left or the right;
the second—whether you are voting for the major or
the minor candidate. Be sure to mention that this is
a sure-fire way to get money out of politics. Try
the line “This penny can't be bought.” Don't argue
or debate; rattle off your “elevator speech,” hand
over the penny and move on. The last detail everyone
needs to remember is how to respond to exit polls,
in order to deprive the other side of any
understanding of what has just happened. When asked
how you voted, say: “I voted by secret ballot.”
Then you can go home, turn on the idiot box and
watch a fun spectacle featuring the gnashing of
teeth, the rending of garments and the scattering of
ashes upon talking heads. You won’t get to see the
behind-the-scenes rancor and the recriminations
among the moneyed elites, but you can imagine just
how furious they will be, having had their billions
of dollars defeated by a few handfuls of pennies.
You might think that random voting, with each
candidate getting an equal share of the votes, would
be perfectly predictable, making it possible to
secure a victory by hacking a few voting machines.
But this would never be the case in the real world,
because not everyone will vote randomly. You might
then think that it would still be possible to
manipulate the nonrandom voters into voting a
certain way. But how can anyone predict who will
vote randomly and who won't? And if every vote is,
in essence, purchased, how would someone go about
buying random votes, or figuring out which candidate
such a purchase would favor? In this situation,
buying votes would only serve to further confuse the
outcome. Thus, the effect of added randomness on the
outcome will not be random; it will be chaotic.
And that, my fellow Americans, is how you can change
a “you lose—they win” outcome to a more just and
equitable “you lose—they lose” in this particular
game of strategy.
Dmitry
Orlov
was born in Leningrad and immigrated to the United
States in the 1970’s. He is the author of
Reinventing Collapse, Hold Your Applause! and
Absolutely Positive, and publishes weekly at the
phenomenally popular blog
www.ClubOrlov.com
.
|