Revolts of
the Debtors: From Socrates to Ibn Khaldun
By Michael Hudson
June 26,
2016 "Information
Clearing House"
- "Counterpunch"
- Last week I attended a wonderful conference in the
university town of Tübingen, Germany, on “Debt: The
First 3500 Years,” to bring ancient historians
together to discuss David Graeber’s book
Debt: The First 5000 Years.
I was
enlightened by two papers in particular. Doctoral
fellow Moritz Hinsch from Berlin collected what
Socrates (470-399 BC) and other Athenians wrote
about debt, and the conference’s organizer, Prof.
John Weisweiler, presented the new view of late
imperial Rome as being still a long way from
outright serfdom. The 99 Percent were squeezed, but
“the economy” grew – in a way that concentrated
growth in the hands of the One Percent. In due
course this bred popular resentment that spread in
the form of debtor revolts, not only in the Roman
Empire but that of Iran as well, leading to
religious reforms to limit the charging of interest
and self-indulgent greed in general.
I had not
been in Tübingen since 1959, and it was my first
chance to meet with David Graeber since he moved to
England to teach at the London School of Economics
after being hounded out of his apartment in New York
City in the wake of the police and FBI crackdown
against Occupy Wall Street. Our mutual German
publisher, Klett-Cotta, sent its senior editor from
nearby Stuttgart to discuss their German translation
of my
Killing the Host, to appear in
November, as Der Sektor: Warum die Globale
Finanzwirtschaft uns Zerstört.
Socrates’ views on whether bad debts should be paid
In Book I
of Plato’s
Republic (380 BC), Socrates discusses
the morality of repaying debts. Cephalus, a
businessman living in the commercial Piraeus
district, states the typical ethic that it is fair
and just to pay back what one has borrowed or
received.[1]
Socrates replies that it would not be just to return
weapons to a man who has turned into a lunatic.
Because of the consequences, paying back the debt
would be the wrong thing to do.
At issue is
not the micro-economic morality of paying a debt,
but how this act affects society. If a madman is
intent on murder, returning his weapon to him will
enable him to commit unjust acts. The morality of
paying back all debts is not necessarily
justice. We need to take the overall consequences
into account.
A similar
logic may apply to today’s debate over whether
Greece should pay back the IMF and European Central
Bank (ECB) for the money that they have provided
since 2010 to save bondholders from losses on loans
(largely by French and German banks). The terms
oblige the Greek government to pay in full instead
of writing down debts to reflect the actual ability
to pay.
The IMF
staff calculated repeatedly that Greece had no way
of paying off these debts, so the IMF violated its
own articles of agreement (and its “No More
Argentinas” rule) that it should not lend to
countries which, in the judgment of its research
staff, have no foreseeable means to pay.[2]
IMF board members also protested to the bondholder
bailout – all to no avail.
The
morality of paying off the IMF and ECB is analogous
to paying off the madman discussed by Socrates. At
issue is what should be saved: wealthy creditors
from loss (and the morality that all debts should be
paid), or the overall economy from unemployment and
misery leading to emigration, worse health and
shorter lifespans. They have used their debt
leverage to demand that Greece impose austerity,
increase unemployment (now running at an enormous 25
percent for IV-2015 – I-2016), scale back pensions
to retirees, and privatize public infrastructure to
pay creditors – while running a budget surplus to
suck even more money out of the economy.
When the
Greek people voted in 2015 to reject these demands,
the ECB and European Union insisted that referendums
didn’t matter. Shifting economic policy from voters
to bankers already had led Frank Schirrmacher to
write an article in the Frankfurter Allgemeine
Zeitung, “Democracy is Junk.”
What really
is at issue is the selfish and abusive behavior of
creditors. Later in the Republic (Book
VIII, 555d-556b), Socrates talks with Glaucon,
pointing to the “negligence and encouragement of
licentiousness in oligarchies.” Their greed,
Socrates explains, inserts the parasitic “sting of
their money into any of the remainder who do not
resist.” The effect is to burden many Athenians with
debt, to suffer foreclosure on their land and
disenfranchisement, fostering “the drone and pauper
element in the state.” This leaves the people (the
demos) to “conspire against the acquirers
of their estates and the rest of the citizens, and
be eager for revolution.”
The way to
quench this disaster in the making, Socrates
suggests, is to enact “a law prohibiting a man from
doing as he likes with his own, or in this way, by a
second law that does away with such abuses.”
“What law?”
asks Glaucon.
“The law
that is next best … commanding that most voluntary
contracts should be at the contractor’s risk. The
pursuit of wealth would be less shameless in the
state and fewer of the evils of which we spoke just
now would grow up there.”
This
obligation of creditors to share in the risk of
non-payment is precisely what the IMF staff and
other critics of the European Central Bank’s
pro-creditor line are now belatedly insisting. It is
the principle that American bank reformers urged
after the 2008 crash: Banks that made junk mortgage
loans beyond the ability of debtors to pay should
have their reckless and often fraudulent “liars’
loans” downsized to reflect reasonable rental values
and real estate prices instead of being allowed to
foreclose and push the U.S. economy into debt
deflation.
Concentration of wealth by Rome’s One Percent leads
debtors to revolt
Roman
emperors sponsored a market economy that aimed at
producing a fiscal surplus, which was used largely
to pay mercenaries. Wealth and political power were
concentrated in the imperial bureaucracy, army
leaders, and their suppliers and provisioners. The
tax reform of Diocletian (ruled 284-305), enacted in
297, taxed the hitherto exempt wealthy landowners as
well as the rest of the economy. His successor,
Constantine (ruled 306-337), enacted a monetary
reform in the 310’s, basing the military-fiscal
state on the gold solidus.
The effect
was monetary deflation. “Like the gold standard of
the nineteenth and twentieth centuries,” Prof.
Weisweiler explained in his paper on the Late Roman
economy, “the introduction of the solidus was a
golden age for capital-owners but a dark period for
lower strata of the population.” Yet Medium-sized
farms survived without being reduced to serfdom, and
wage labor was available for hire at harvest time.
The proportion of Italy’s population enslaved is now
deemed to have been around 15 percent.
There were
no slave revolts, but debtors rebelled or defected
to invaders, as they had done earlier in antiquity.
Prof. Weisweiler described how, when a Gothic army
defeated that of Rome at Adrianople (eastern Turkey)
in 378, local guides brought the victors “to the
villas of great landowners, who were then plundered
by a coalition of Gothic soldiers and local
residents. When in 408 the Romano-Gothic military
leader Alaric for the first time besieged the city
of Rome, his forces were swollen by many debtors who
left the imperial capital to join his army.”
Richard
Payne of the University of Chicago gave a paper
explaining how peasant revolts against Persia’s
Sasanian rulers a century later sought to “restore”
an egalitarian Zoroastrian order as a protest
against the extreme polarization that widened the
gap between luxury and poverty. The new morality of
economic balance rejected silk garments, silver wine
vessels and other status symbols of the elites.
Interest was condemned, as it had been under
Christianity and would be under Islam. All religious
urged mutual aid and warned about abusive
wealth-seeking by the elites. What occurred
culturally was a revulsion against luxury and
hubris – a Greek word that connoted not only
arrogance, but arrogance that took the form of
injuring others.
Ideology and antiquity
Creditors
were the typical class singled out as oppressive and
destructive of society. Their self-centered wealth
addiction was seen as stripping society to serve
their own compulsive drives. It was to praise
moderation and even to prefer a poverty of equality
to indulgence in luxury that Christianity, Islam and
other religious movements of the early first
millennium AD took root.
By the 14th
century the great Tunisian Islamic philosopher of
history, Ibn Khaldun, described societies gaining
prosperity through “group feeling,” only to lose it
within about 120 years as the ruling dynasty
succumbed to self-indulgence and greed – paving the
way for their land to be conquered from without or
taken over from within.
My
own paper for the conference described how Ibn
Khaldun’s “rise and fall” view of history in
The Muqaddimah was echoed in Giambatisto
Vico’s
The New Science (1725), and later by
the French and Scottish Enlightenment by writers
such as Adam Ferguson, who endorsed Montesquieu’s
statement in
Spirit of the Laws (1748): “Man is born
in society, and there he remains.” To survive,
people need to cooperate in a system of mutual aid.
“Man is, by nature, the member of a community; and
when considered in this capacity, the individual
appears to be no longer made for himself. He must
forego his happiness and his freedom, where these
interfere with the good of society.”[3]
All this
teaches the opposite of today’s two guiding economic
premises: “Greed is good,” and “There is no such
thing as society.” Economics used to be called moral
philosophy, but it has succumbed to individualistic
extremism. Homo economicus has replaced
zoon politikon. Debts are supposed to be paid
without concern for how this impoverishes the
economy.
It was to
resist personal gain-seeking at the expense of the
body politic and group solidarity that the world’s
major philosophies and religions for the past two
thousand years urged self-control, generosity, care
for the weak and poor, and rules to limit the
luxurious self-indulgence and anti-social egotism it
bred in ruling elites. Excluding this intellectual
legacy from the curriculum has paved the way for
inverting today’s moral attitude upholding creditor
claims against the rest of society.
It should
not be surprising that modern financial elites are
fighting back against democratic moves to limit
their wealth, adopt progressive taxation, write down
debts by bankruptcy reform, and shift control of
government away from landed aristocracies and
banking centers. These vested interests are behaving
exactly as Ibn Khaldun described the terminal
decadent generation of dynasties as acting with
anti-social selfishness.
Ferguson described how prosperity lay the groundwork
for undermining the commercial stage: “man is
sometimes found a detached and a solitary being: he
has found an object which sets him in competition
with his fellow creatures, and he deals with them as
he does with his cattle and his soil, for the sake
of the profits they bring. The mighty engine which
we suppose to have formed society, only tends to set
its members at variance, or to continue their
intercourse after the bonds of affection are
broken.”[4]
The
financial takeover of government is not new. Ibn
Khaldun described how what today is called the “deep
state” (often run by foreigners or other
interlopers) gains control of dynasties. Lacking
traditional royal authority, they must work outside
or behind the scene of politics, as finance does
today:
In
gaining control, he does not plan to appropriate
royal authority for himself openly, but only to
appropriate its fruits, that is, the exercise of
administrative, executive, and all other power. He
gives the people of the dynasty the impression that
he merely acts for the ruler and executes the
latter’s decisions from behind the curtain. He
carefully refrains from using the attributes,
emblems, or titles of royal authority. He avoids
throwing any suspicion upon himself in this respect,
even though he exercises full control. … He
disguises his exercise of control under the form of
acting as the ruler’s representative.[5]
Today’s
Treasury Secretaries, central bank heads, IMF
economists and client academics serve the world’s
cosmopolitan financial ideology that money and
credit, debt and taxes are purely technocratic, and
hence beyond the sphere of voters or the politicians
they elect to “interfere” with. We are back with the
Thatcherite financial Taliban (the Arab word for
“students”): There Is No Alternative.
That is the
protective myth that elites have wrapped around
themselves and their privileges from time
immemorial. To succeed, it must erase knowledge of
history and live in a highly censored “present” in
which the financial class takes the land, public
infrastructure and government into its own hands.
It has all
happened before – and so have revolts by debtors and
other exploited victims of such “economism.”
Notes.
[1] Plato,
Republic, 331c-d. The term for justice is
dikaiosyne, meaning “right behavior,” from
dike, cognate to dexterous. I am
indebted to Moritz Hinsch of Berlin for drawing my
attention to this passage in his paper on “Private
Debts in Classical Greece,” delivered to the
international conference on “Debt: The First 3500
Years” in Tübingen, Germany, June 11, 2016.
[2] I
review the IMF staff protests and Board complaints
about the Greek loan in Killing the Host
(2015), pp. 303-306, 310, 319f. and 335f.
[3] Adam
Ferguson,
Essay on the History of Civil Society
[1767], 8th ed. (1819), Section IX: Of
National Felicity, p. 105. He adds (pp. 4f.): “both
the earliest and the latest accounts collected from
every quarter of the earth, represent mankind as
assembled in troops and companies; and the
individual always joined by affection to one party,
while he is possibly opposed to another.”
[4]
Ferguson, History of Civil Society, p. 34.
[5] Ibn
Khaldun, Muqaddimah, : An Introduction
to History [1377] translated by Franz Rosenthal
(Princeton, 1967 [first ed. 1958]), pp. 377-79.
|