Some
Real Costs of the Trans-Pacific Partnership: Nearly
Half a Million Jobs Lost in the US Alone
By Jomo Kwame Sundaram
March 01, 2016 "Information
Clearing House"
- "NC"
- The Trans-Pacifc Partnership (TPP) Agreement,
recently agreed to by twelve Pacifc Rim countries
led by the United States,1 promises to
ease many restrictions on cross-border transactions
and harmonize regulations. Proponents of the
agreement have claimed significant economic
benefits, citing modest overall net GDP gains,
ranging from half of one percent in the United
States to 13 percent in Vietnam after fifteen years.
Their claims, however, rely on many unjustified
assumptions, including full employment in every
country and no resulting impacts on working people’s
incomes, with more than 90 percent of overall growth
gains due to ‘non-trade measures’ with varying
impacts.
A recent GDAE
Working Paper finds that with more realistic
methodological assumptions, critics of the TPP
indeed have reason to be concerned. Using the trade
projections for the most optimistic growth
forecasts, we find that the TPP is more likely to
lead to net employment losses in many countries
(771,000 jobs lost overall, with 448,000 in the
United States alone) and higher inequality in all
country groupings. Declining worker purchasing power
would weaken aggregate demand, slowing economic
growth. The United States (-0.5 percent) and Japan
(-0.1 percent) are projected to suffer small net
income losses, not gains, from the TPP.
This GDAE
Policy Brief is intended to help clarify the
differences with other modeling studies and to
present our findings in a less technical manner.
Flaws in TPP Economic Projections
Optimistic claims about the TPP’s economic impacts
are largely based on economic modeling projections
published by the Washington-based Peterson Institute
for International Economics.2 Its
researchers used a computable general equilibrium
(CGE) model to project net GDP gains for all
countries involved. These figures have been widely
cited in many countries to justify TPP approval and
ratification. Updated estimates, released in early
2016 and incorporated into the World Bank’s latest
report on the global economy,3 now stress
income gains for the United States of $131 billion,
or 0.5 percent of GDP, and a 9.1 percent increase in
exports by 2030.4
The
projections methodology assumes away critical
economic problems and boosts economic growth
estimates with unfounded assumptions. The assumption
of full employment is particularly problematic.
Workers will inevitably be displaced due to the TPP,
but CGE modelers assume that all dismissed workers
will be promptly rehired elsewhere in the national
economy as if part of labor ‘churning’. The
full-employment assumption thus inflates projected
GDP gains by assuming away job losses and adjustment
costs.
The
modelers also dismiss increases in inequality by
assuming no changes to wage and profit shares of
national income. Again, this is not supported by
empirical evidence, as past trade agreements have
tended to reduce labor’s share.
Finally,
foreign direct investment (FDI) is assumed to
increase dramatically, which contributes a
significant boost to economic growth in the Peterson
Institute projections, accounting for more than 25
percent of projected U.S. economic gains in the
recent update. This assumes that: 1) income to
capital owners will be invested; and 2) this will
result in broad-based growth. Neither is supported
by the evidence. A U.S. Department of Agriculture
study,5 which did not assume such
FDI-related investment gains, found zero growth for
the United States and very modest growth elsewhere
at best.
The
methodology of the Peterson study is flawed;
consequently, growth and income gains are
overstated, and the costs to working people,
consumers and governments are understated, ignored
or even presented as benefits. Job losses and
declining or stagnant labor incomes are excluded
from consideration, even though they lower economic
growth by reducing aggregate demand.
Some
economists have pointed out6 additional
misleading findings in the most recent Peterson
Institute update:
• U.S.
income gains of 0.5 percent from TPP in 2030 –
This is raised from the institute’s previous 0.4
percent, mainly by extending the implementation
period from ten to fifteen years. In any case,
added growth of 0.5 percent is very small, about
0.03 percent per year over fifteen years.
•
Exports rise by 9.1 percent, but so do imports,
because the model assumes fixed trade balances.
This excludes, by assumption, the problems
associated with rising trade deficits, which
have been common after previous trade
agreements.
• All
displaced workers are absorbed immediately and
costlessly in other sectors – again, by
assumption. The paper does acknowledge that
manufacturing employment will increase more
slowly because of the TPP, and that some 53,700
more U.S. jobs per year will be “displaced”
annually. But they view this as a small addition
to normal labor market “churn.”
More Realistic Economic Projections
We employed
the UN Global Policy Model (GPM) to generate more
realistic projections of likely TPP impacts. Unlike
most CGE models, the GPM incorporates more realistic
assumptions about economic adjustment and income
distribution, assessing the TPP impact on each of
them as well as on economic growth over a ten-year
period. Importantly, it does not assume large
unexplained FDI surges or investment, growth and
income gains due to nontrade measures. The modeling
results are summarized in the table.
To
facilitate comparison, we used the Peterson
Institute’s projected estimates of the TPP’s impact
on exports, applying the macroeconomic model to
assess the efects of projected TPP trade increases.7
The GPM analyzes macroeconomic sectors – primary
commodities, energy, manufacturing and services –
but does not contain data on single markets (such as
car parts or poultry).
The main
fndings include:
• The
TPP will generate net GDP losses in the USA and
Japan. Ten years after the treaty comes into
force, US GDP is projected to be 0.54 percent
lower than it would be without the TPP.
Similarly, the TPP is projected to reduce
Japan’s growth by 0.12 percent.
• For
other TPP countries, economic gains will be
negligible – less than one percent over ten
years for developed countries, and less than
three percent over the decade for developing
countries. Chile and Peru’s combined gain of
2.84 percent comes to only about a quarter of
one percent per year.
• The
TPP is projected to lead to employment losses
overall, with a total of 771,000 jobs lost. The
United States will be hardest hit, losing
448,000 jobs.
• The
TPP will also likely lead to higher inequality
due to declining labor shares of national
incomes. In the United States, labor shares are
projected to fall by 1.31 percent over ten
years, continuing an ongoing multi-decade
downward trend.
Conclusions
In sum, the
TPP will increase pressures on labor incomes,
weakening domestic demand in all participating
countries, in turn leading to lower employment and
higher inequality. Even though countries with lower
labor costs may gain greater market shares and small
GDP increases, employment is still likely to fall
and inequality to increase.
In fact,
most goods trade among TPP countries has already
been liberalized by earlier agreements. Instead of
promoting growth and employment, the TPP is mainly
about imposing new rules favored by large
multinational corporations. The TPP greatly
strengthens investor and intellectual property
rights (IPRs), while weakening national regulation,
e.g. over financial services.
The TPP
will strengthen IPRs for big pharmaceutical,
information technology, media, and other firms, e.g.
by allowing pharmaceutical companies longer
monopolies on patented medicines, keeping cheaper
generics of the market, and blocking the development
and availability of similar new medicines.
The TPP
would also strengthen foreign investor rights at the
expense of local businesses and the public interest.
The TPP’s investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS)
system will oblige governments to compensate foreign
investors for losses of expected profits in binding
private arbitration.
These
pro-investor measures impose significant costs,
especially on developing countries. They will exert
a chilling efect on important government
responsibilities to promote national development and
protect the public interest.
Our
modeling suggests that TPP skeptics, concerned about
the agreement’s impacts on growth, labor incomes,
employment and inequality, have good reason to doubt
optimistic projections. Our results show negative
impacts in all these areas, particularly in the
United States. Legislatures in TPP countries should
carefully consider these findings and their
implications before approving the agreement.
Jomo Kwame Sundaram, an Assistant Secretary General
working on Economic Development in the United
Nations system during 2005-15, and was awarded the
2007 Wassily Leontief Prize for Advancing the
Frontiers of Economic Thought. Originally published
as a
Global Development and
Environment Institute Policy Brief
Endnotes
1 The
participating countries – Canada, United States,
Mexico, Chile, Peru, Japan, Vietnam, Malaysia,
Singapore, Brunei, Australia and New Zealand – have
finalized and signed the text of the agreement, but
the treaty must be ratified in all of them before it
can come into force.
2 Peter
Petri, Michael Plummer and Fan Zhai (2012). “The
Trans-Pacific Partnership and Asia-Pacific
Integration: A Quantitative Assessment”. Policy
Analyses in International Economics 98, Peterson
Institute for International Economics, Washington,
DC. The Peterson Institute study has also been
criticized by others, e.g.
http://www.sustainabilitynz.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/02/EconomicGainsandCostsfromtheTPP_2014.pdf.
3 See
Global Economic Prospects, Spillovers Amid Weak
Recovery, January 2016, The World Bank Group,
Washington, DC.
4 Peter
Petri and Michael Plummer, “The Economic Efects of
the Trans-Pacifc Partnership: New Estimates”,
January 2016, Working Paper 16-2, Peterson Institute
for International Economics, Washington, DC.
5 See
http://www.ers.usda.gov/media/1692509/err176.pdf
6 See, for
example, Dean Baker, “Peterson
Institute Study Shows TPP Will Lead to $357 Billion
Increase in Annual Imports”, January 26, 2016.
7 A robust
debate over such modeling followed the release of
the GDAE paper, with a critique from Robert Lawrence
for the Peterson Institute (“Studies
of TPP: Which is Credible?”) and two responses
from GDAE: “Are
the Peterson Institute Studies Reliable Guides to
Likely TPP Effects?” and “Modeling
TPP: A response to Robert Z. Lawrence.” GDAE
clarifed that the GPM is fully documented in the
UNCTAD publication, “The
UN Global Policy Model: Technical Description.”
|