The IMF
Changes its Rules to Isolate China and Russia
By Michael
Hudson -
Guns and
Butter
Dr. Hudson discusses his paper, The IMF Changes
Its Rules To Isolate China and Russia;
implications of the four policy changes at the
International Monetary Fund in its role as
enforcer of inter-government debts; the Shanghai
Cooperation Organization (SCO) as an alternative
military alliance to NATO; the Asian
Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) threatens
to replace the IMF and World Bank; the Trans
Pacific Partnership Treaty; the China
International Payments System (CIPS); WTO
investment treaties; Ukraine and Greece;
different philosophies of development between
east and west; break up of the post WWII
dollarized global financial system; the world
dividing into two camps.
Posted
February 05, 2016
A New
Global Financial Cold War
By
Michael Hudson
A nightmare
scenario of U.S. geopolitical strategists is coming
true: foreign independence from U.S.-centered
financial and diplomatic control. China and Russia
are investing in neighboring economies on terms that
cement Eurasian integration on the basis of
financing in their own currencies and favoring their
own exports. They also have created the Shanghai
Cooperation Organization (SCO) as an alternative
military alliance to NATO.[1]
And the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB)
threatens to replace the IMF and World Bank tandem
in which the United States holds unique veto power.
More than
just a disparity of voting rights in the IMF and
World Bank is at stake. At issue is a philosophy of
development. U.S. and other foreign investment in
infrastructure (or buyouts and takeovers on credit)
adds interest rates and other financial charges to
the cost structure, while charging prices as high as
the market can bear (think of Carlos Slim’s
telephone monopoly in Mexico, or the high costs of
America’s health care system), and making their
profits and monopoly rents tax-exempt by paying them
out as interest.
By
contrast, government-owned infrastructure provides
basic services at low cost, on a subsidized basis,
or freely. That is what has made the United States,
Germany and other industrial lead nations so
competitive over the past few centuries. But this
positive role of government is no longer possible
under World Bank/IMF policy. The U.S. promotion of
neoliberalism and austerity is a major reason
propelling China, Russia and other nations out of
the U.S. diplomatic and banking orbit.
On December
3, 2015, Prime Minister Putin proposed that Russia
“and other Eurasian Economic Union countries should
kick-off consultations with members of the SCO and
the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)
on a possible economic partnership.”[2]
Russia also is seeking to build pipelines to Europe
through friendly secular countries instead of Sunni
jihadist U.S.-backed countries locked into America’s
increasingly confrontational orbit.
Russian finance minister Anton Siluanov points out
that when Russia’s 2013 loan to Ukraine was made, at
the request of Ukraine’s elected government,
Ukraine’s “international reserves were barely enough
to cover three months’ imports, and no other
creditor was prepared to lend on terms acceptable to
Kiev. Yet Russia provided $3 billion of much-needed
funding at a 5 per cent interest rate, when
Ukraine’s bonds were yielding nearly 12 per cent.”[3]
What
especially annoys U.S. financial strategists is that
this loan by Russia’s National Wealth Fund was
protected by IMF lending practice, which at that
time ensured collectability by withholding credit
from countries in default of foreign official debts,
or at least not bargaining in good faith to pay. To
cap matters, the bonds are registered under London’s
creditor-oriented rules and courts.
Most
worrisome to U.S. strategists is that China and
Russia are denominating their trade and investment
in their own currencies instead of dollars. After
U.S. officials threatened to derange Russia’s
banking linkages by cutting it off from the SWIFT
interbank clearing system, China accelerated its
creation of the alternative China International
Payments System (CIPS), and its own credit card
system to protect Eurasian economies from the
threats made by U.S. unilateralists.
Russia and
China are simply doing what the United States has
long done: using trade and credit linkages to cement
their diplomacy. This tectonic geopolitical shift is
a Copernican threat to New Cold War ideology:
Instead of the world economy revolving around the
United States (the Ptolemaic idea of America as “the
indispensible nation”), it may revolve around
Eurasia. As long as global financial control remains
grounded in Washington at the offices of the IMF and
World Bank, such a shift in the center of gravity
will be fought with all the power of an American
Century (and would-be American Millennium)
inquisition.
Any
inquisition needs a court system and enforcement
vehicles. So does resistance to such a system. That
is what today’s global financial, legal and trade
maneuvering is all about. And that is why today’s
world system is in the process of breaking apart.
Differences in economic philosophy call for
different institutions.
To U.S.
neocons the specter of AIIB government-to-government
investment creates fear of nations minting their own
money and holding each other’s debt in their
international reserves instead of borrowing dollars,
paying interest in dollars and subordinating their
financial planning to the U.S. Treasury and IMF.
Foreign governments would have less need to finance
their budget deficits by selling off key
infrastructure. And instead of dismantling public
spending, a broad Eurasian economic union would do
what the United States itself practices, and seek
self-sufficiency in banking and monetary policy.
Imagine the
following scenario five years from now. China will
have spent half a decade building high-speed
railroads, ports, power systems and other
construction for Asian and African countries,
enabling them to grow and export more. These exports
will be coming online to repay the infrastructure
loans. Also, suppose that Russia has been supplying
the oil and gas energy for these projects on credit.
To avert
this prospect, suppose an American diplomat makes
the following proposal to the leaders of countries
in debt to China, Russia and the AIIB: “Now that
you’ve got your increased production in place, why
repay? We’ll make you rich if you stiff our
adversaries and turn back to the West. We and our
European allies will support your assigning your
nations’ public infrastructure to yourselves and
your supporters at insider prices, and then give
these assets market value by selling shares in New
York and London. Then, you can keep the money and
spend it in the West.”
How can
China or Russia collect in such a situation? They
can sue. But what court in the West will accept
their jurisdiction?
That is the
kind of scenario U.S. State Department and Treasury
officials have been discussing for more than a year.
Implementing it became more pressing in light of
Ukraine’s $3 billion debt to Russia falling due by
December 20, 2015. Ukraine’s U.S.-backed regime has
announced its intention to default. To support their
position, the IMF has just changed its rules to
remove a critical lever on which Russia and other
governments have long relied to ensure payment of
their loans.
The IMF’s role as enforcer of
inter-government debts
When it comes to enforcing nations to pay
inter-government debts, the IMF is able to withhold
not only its own credit but also that of governments
and global bank consortia participating when debtor
countries need “stabilization” loans (the neoliberal
euphemism for imposing austerity and destabilizing
debtor economies, as in Greece this year). Countries
that do not privatize their infrastructure and sell
it to Western buyers are threatened with sanctions,
backed by U.S.-sponsored “regime change” and
“democracy promotion” Maidan-style. The Fund’s
creditor leverage has been that if a nation is in
financial arrears to any government, it cannot
qualify for an IMF loan – and hence, for packages
involving other governments. That is how the
dollarized global financial system has worked for
half a century. But until now, the beneficiaries
have been U.S. and NATO lenders, not been China or
Russia.
The
focus on a mixed public/private economy sets the
AIIB at odds with the Trans-Pacific Partnership’s
aim of relinquishing government planning power to
the financial and corporate sector, and the
neoliberal aim of blocking governments from creating
their own money and implementing their own
financial, economic and environmental regulation.
Chief Nomura economist Richard Koo, explained the
logic of viewing the AIIB as a threat to the
U.S.-controlled IMF: “If the IMF’s rival is heavily
under China’s influence, countries receiving its
support will rebuild their economies under what is
effectively Chinese guidance, increasing the
likelihood they will fall directly or indirectly
under that country’s influence.”[4]
This was
the setting on December 8, when Chief IMF Spokesman
Gerry Rice announced: “The IMF’s Executive Board met
today and agreed to change the current policy on
non-toleration of arrears to official creditors.”
Russian Finance Minister Anton Siluanov accused the
IMF decision of being “hasty and biased.”[5]
But it had been discussed all year long, calculating
a range of scenarios for a sea change in
international law. Anders Aslund, senior fellow at
the NATO-oriented Atlantic Council, points out:
The IMF staff started contemplating a rule
change in the spring of 2013 because
nontraditional creditors, such as China, had
started providing developing countries with
large loans. One issue was that these loans were
issued on conditions out of line with IMF
practice. China wasn’t a member of the Paris
Club, where loan restructuring is usually
discussed, so it was time to update the rules.
The IMF intended to adopt a new policy in the
spring of 2016, but the dispute over Russia’s $3
billion loan to Ukraine has accelerated an
otherwise slow decision-making process.[6]
The target
was not only Russia and its ability to collect on
its sovereign loan to Ukraine, but China even more,
in its prospective role as creditor to African
countries and prospective AIIB borrowers, planning
for a New Silk Road to integrate a Eurasian economy
independent of U.S. financial and trade control. The
Wall Street Journal concurred that the main motive
for changing the rules was the threat that China
would provide an alternative to IMF lending and its
demands for crushing austerity. “IMF-watchers said
the fund was originally thinking of ensuring China
wouldn’t be able to foil IMF lending to member
countries seeking bailouts as Beijing ramped up
loans to developing economies around the world.”[7]
So U.S. officials walked into the IMF headquarters
in Washington with the legal equivalent of suicide
vests. Their aim was a last-ditch attempt to block
trade and financial agreements organized outside of
U.S. control and that of the IMF and World Bank.
The plan is
simple enough. Trade follows finance, and the
creditor usually calls the tune. That is how the
United States has used the Dollar Standard to steer
Third World trade and investment since World War II
along lines benefiting the U.S. economy. The cement
of trade credit and bank lending is the ability of
creditors to collect on the international debts
being negotiated. That is why the United States and
other creditor nations have used the IMF as an
intermediary to act as “honest broker” for loan
consortia. (“Honest broker” means being subject to
U.S. veto power.) To enforce its financial leverage,
the IMF has long followed the rule that it will not
sponsor any loan agreement or refinancing for
governments that are in default of debts owed to
other governments. However, as the afore-mentioned
Aslund explains, the IMF could easily
change its practice of not lending into
[countries in official] arrears … because it is
not incorporated into the IMF Articles of
Agreement, that is, the IMF statutes. The IMF
Executive Board can decide to change this policy
with a simple board majority. The IMF has lent
to Afghanistan, Georgia, and Iraq in the midst
of war, and Russia has no veto right, holding
only 2.39 percent of the votes in the IMF. When
the IMF has lent to Georgia and Ukraine, the
other members of its Executive Board have
overruled Russia.[8]
After
the rules change, Aslund later noted, “the IMF can
continue to give Ukraine loans regardless of what
Ukraine does about its credit from Russia, which
falls due on December 20.[9]
The IMF
rule that no country can borrow if it is in default
to a foreign government was created in the post-1945
world. Since then, the U.S. Government, Treasury
and/or U.S. bank consortia have been party to nearly
every major loan agreement. But inasmuch as
Ukraine’s official debt to Russia’s National Wealth
Fund was not to the U.S. Government, the IMF
announced its rules change simply as a
“clarification.” What its rule really meant was that
it would not provide credit to countries in arrears
to the U.S. government, not that of Russia or China.
It
remains up to the IMF board – and in the end, its
managing director – whether or not to deem a country
creditworthy. The U.S. representative can block any
foreign leaders not beholden to the United States.
Mikhail Delyagin, Director of the Institute of
Globalization Problems, explained the double
standard at work: “The Fund will give Kiev a new
loan tranche on one condition: that Ukraine should
not pay Russia a dollar under its $3 billion debt. …
they will oblige Ukraine to pay only to western
creditors for political reasons.”[10]
The
post-2010 loan packages to Greece are a case in
point. The IMF staff saw that Greece could not
possibly pay the sums needed to bail out French,
German and other foreign banks and bondholders. Many
Board members agreed, and have gone public with
their whistle blowing. Their protests didn’t matter.
President Barack Obama and Treasury Secretary Tim
Geithner pointed out that U.S. banks had written
credit default swaps betting that Greece could pay,
and would lose money if there were a debt
writedown). Dominique Strauss-Kahn backed the hard
line US- European Central Bank position. So did
Christine Lagarde in 2015, overriding staff
protests.[11]
Regarding
Ukraine, IMF executive board member Otaviano Canuto,
representing Brazil, noted that the logic that
“conditions on IMF lending to a country that fell
behind on payments [was to] make sure it kept
negotiating in good faith to reach agreement with
creditors.”[12]
Dropping this condition, he said, would open the
door for other countries to insist on a similar
waiver and avoid making serious and sincere efforts
to reach payment agreement with creditor
governments.
A more
binding IMF rule is Article I of its 1944-45
founding charter, prohibiting the Fund from lending
to a member state engaged in civil war or at war
with another member state, or for military purposes
in general. But when IMF head Lagarde made the last
loan to Ukraine, in spring 2015, she merely
expressed a vapid token hope there might be peace.
Withholding IMF credit could have been a lever to
force peace and adherence to the Minsk agreements,
but U.S. diplomatic pressure led that opportunity to
be rejected. President Porochenko immediately
announced that he would step up the civil war with
the Russian-speaking population in the eastern
Donbass region.
The
most important IMF condition being violated is that
continued warfare with the East prevents a realistic
prospect of Ukraine paying back new loans. The
Donbas is where most Ukrainian exports were made,
mainly to Russia. That market is being lost by the
junta’s belligerence toward Russia. This should have
blocked Ukraine from receiving IMF aid. Aslund
himself points to the internal contradiction at
work: Ukraine has achieved budget balance because
the inflation and steep currency depreciation has
drastically eroded its pension costs. But the
resulting decline in the purchasing power of pension
benefits has led to growing opposition to Ukraine’s
post-Maidan junta. So how can the IMF’s austerity
budget be followed without a political backlash?
“Leading representatives from President Petro
Poroshenko’s Bloc are insisting on massive tax cuts,
but no more expenditure cuts; that would cause a
vast budget deficit that the IMF assesses at 9-10
percent of GDP, that could not possibly be
financed.”[13]
By
welcoming and financing Ukraine instead of treating
as an outcast, the IMF thus is breaking four of its
rules:
- Not to
lend to a country that has no visible means to
pay back the loan. This breaks the “No More
Argentinas” rule, adopted after the IMF’s
disastrous 2001 loan.
- Not to
lend to a country that repudiates its debt to
official creditors. This goes against the IMF’s
role as enforcer for the global creditor cartel.
- Not to
lend to a borrower at war – and indeed, to one
that is destroying its export capacity and hence
its balance-of-payments ability to pay back the
loan.
-
Finally, not to lend to a country that is not
likely to carry out the IMF’s austerity
“conditionalities,” at least without crushing
democratic opposition in a totalitarian manner.
The upshot
– and new basic guideline for IMF lending – is to
split the world into pro-U.S. economies going
neoliberal, and economies maintaining public
investment in infrastructure n and what used to be
viewed as progressive capitalism. Russia and China
may lend as much as they want to other governments,
but there is no global vehicle to help secure their
ability to be paid back under international law.
Having refused to roll back its own (and ECB) claims
on Greece, the IMF is willing to see countries not
on the list approved by U.S. neocons repudiate their
official debts to Russia or China. Changing its
rules to clear the path for making loans to Ukraine
is rightly seen as an escalation of America’s New
Cold War against Russia and China.
Timing is
everything in such ploys. Georgetown University Law
professor and Treasury consultant Anna Gelpern
warned that before the “IMF staff and executive
board [had] enough time to change the policy on
arrears to official creditors,” Russia might use
“its notorious debt/GDP clause to accelerate the
bonds at any time before December, or simply gum up
the process of reforming the IMF’s arrears policy.”[14]
According to this clause, if Ukraine’s foreign debt
rose above 60 percent of GDP, Russia’s government
would have the right to demand immediate payment.
But President Putin, no doubt anticipating the
bitter fight to come over its attempts to collect on
its loan, refrained from exercising this option. He
is playing the long game, bending over backward to
behave in a way that cannot be criticized as
“odious.”
A more
immediate reason deterring the United States from
pressing earlier to change IMF rules was the need to
use the old set of rules against Greece before
changing them for Ukraine. A waiver for Ukraine
would have provided a precedent for Greece to ask
for a similar waiver on paying the “troika” – the
European Central Bank (ECB), EU commission and the
IMF itself – for the post-2010 loans that have
pushed it into a worse depression than the 1930s.
Only after Greece capitulated to eurozone austerity
was the path clear for U.S. officials to change the
IMF rules to isolate Russia. But their victory has
come at the cost of changing the IMF’s rules and
those of the global financial system irreversibly.
Other countries henceforth may reject
conditionalities, as Ukraine has done, as well as
asking for write-downs on foreign official debts.
That
was the great fear of neoliberal U.S. and Eurozone
strategists last summer, after all. The reason for
smashing Greece’s economy was to deter Podemos in
Spain and similar movements in Italy and Portugal
from pursuing national prosperity instead of
eurozone austerity. “Imagine the Greek government
had insisted that EU institutions accept the same
haircut as the country’s private creditors,” Russian
finance minister Anton Siluanov asked. “The reaction
in European capitals would have been frosty. Yet
this is the position now taken by Kiev with respect
to Ukraine’s $3 billion eurobond held by Russia.”[15]
The
consequences of America’s tactics to make a
financial hit on Russia while its balance of
payments is down (as a result of collapsing oil and
gas prices) go far beyond just the IMF. These
tactics are driving other countries to defend their
own economies in the legal and political spheres, in
ways that are breaking apart the post-1945 global
order.
Countering Russia’s ability to
collect in Britain’s law courts
Over the past year the U.S. Treasury and State
Departments have discussed ploys to block Russia
from collecting by suing in the London Court of
International Arbitration, under whose rules
Russia’s bonds issued to Ukraine are registered.
Reviewing the excuses Ukraine might use to avoid
paying Russia, Prof. Gelpern noted that it might
declare the debt “odious,” made under duress or
corruptly. In a paper for the Peterson Institute of
International Economics (the banking lobby in
Washington) she suggested that Britain should deny
Russia the use of its courts as a means of
reinforcing the financial, energy and trade
sanctions passed after Crimea voted to join Russia
as protection against the ethnic cleansing from the
Right Sector, Azov Battalion and other paramilitary
groups descending on the region.[16]
A kindred
ploy might be for Ukraine to countersue Russia for
reparations for “invading” it and taking Crimea.
Such a claim would seem to have little chance of
success (without showing the court to be an arm of
NATO politics), but it might delay Russia’ ability
to collect by tying the loan up in a long nuisance
lawsuit. But the British court would lose
credibility if it permits frivolous legal claims
(called barratry in English) such as President
Poroshenko and Prime Minister Yatsenyuk have
threatened.
To claim
that Ukraine’s debt to Russia was “odious” or
otherwise illegitimate, “President Petro Poroshenko
said the money was intended to ensure Yanukovych’s
loyalty to Moscow, and called the payment a ‘bribe,’
according to an interview with Bloomberg in June
this year.”[17]
The legal and moral problem with such arguments is
that they would apply equally to IMF and U.S. loans.
They would open the floodgates for other countries
to repudiate debts taken on by dictatorships
supported by IMF and U.S. lenders.
As
Foreign Minister Sergei Lavrov noted, the IMF’s
change of rules, “designed to suit Ukraine only,
could plant a time bomb under all other IMF
programs.” The new rules showed the extent to which
the IMF is subordinate to U.S. aggressive New Cold
Warriors: “since Ukraine is politically important –
and it is only important because it is opposed to
Russia – the IMF is ready to do for Ukraine
everything it has not done for anyone else.”[18]
In a
similar vein, Andrei Klimov, deputy chairman of the
Committee for International Affairs at the
Federation Council (the upper house of Russia’s
parliament) accused the United States of playing
“the role of the main violin in the IMF while the
role of the second violin is played by the European
Union, [the] two basic sponsors of the Maidan – the
… coup d’état in Ukraine in 2014.”[19]
Putin’s counter-strategy and the
blowback on U.S.-European relations
Having anticipated that Ukraine would seek excuses
to not pay Russia, President Putin refrained from
exercising Russia’s right to demand immediate
payment when Ukraine’s foreign debt rose above 60
percent of GDP. In November he even offered to defer
any payment at all this year, stretching payments
out to “$1 billion next year, $1 billion in 2017,
and $1 billion in 2018,” if “the United States
government, the European Union, or one of the big
international financial institutions” guaranteed
payment.[20]
Based on their assurances “that Ukraine’s solvency
will grow,” he added, they should be willing to put
their money where their mouth was. If they did not
provide guarantees, Putin pointed out, “this means
that they do not believe in the Ukrainian economy’s
future.”
Implicit
was that if the West continued encouraging Ukraine
to fight against the East, its government would not
be in a position to pay. The Minsk agreement was
expiring and Ukraine was receiving new arms support
from the United States, Canada and other NATO
members to intensify hostilities against Donbas and
Crimea.
But
the IMF, European Union and United States refused to
back up the Fund’s optimistic forecast of Ukraine’s
ability to pay in the face of its continued civil
war against the East. Foreign Minister Lavrov
concluded that, “By having refused to guarantee
Ukraine’s debt as part of Russia’s proposal to
restructure it, the United States effectively
admitted the absence of prospects of restoring its
solvency.”[21]
In an
exasperated tone, Prime Minister Dmitry Medvedev
said on Russian television: “I have a feeling that
they won’t give us the money back because they are
crooks … and our Western partners not only refuse to
help, but they also make it difficult for us.”
Accusing that “the international financial system is
unjustly structured,” he nonetheless promised to “go
to court. We’ll push for default on the loan and
we’ll push for default on all Ukrainian debts,”
based on the fact that the loan
was a request from the Ukrainian Government to
the Russian Government. If two governments reach
an agreement this is obviously a sovereign
loan…. Surprisingly, however, international
financial organisations started saying that this
is not exactly a sovereign loan. This is utter
bull. Evidently, it’s just an absolutely brazen,
cynical lie. … This seriously erodes trust in
IMF decisions. I believe that now there will be
a lot of pleas from different borrower states to
the IMF to grant them the same terms as Ukraine.
How will the IMF possibly refuse them?[22]
And
there the matter stands. On December 16, 2015, the
IMF’s Executive Board ruled that “the bond should be
treated as official debt, rather than a commercial
bond.”[23]
Forbes quipped: “Russia apparently is not always
blowing smoke. Sometimes they’re actually telling it
like it is.”[24]
Reflecting the degree of hatred fanned by U.S.
diplomacy, U.S.-backed Ukrainian Finance Minister
Natalie A. Jaresko expressed an arrogant confidence
that the IMF would back the Ukrainian cabinet’s
announcement on Friday, December 18, of its
intention to default on the debt to Russia falling
due two days later. “If we were to repay this bond
in full, it would mean we failed to meet the terms
of the I.M.F. and the obligations we made under our
restructuring.”[25]
Adding his
own bluster, Prime Minister Arseny Yatsenyuk
announced his intention to tie up Russia’s claim for
payment by filing a multibillion-dollar counter
claim “over Russia’s occupation of Crimea and
intervention in east Ukraine.” To cap matters, he
added that “several hundred million dollars of debt
owed by two state enterprises to Russian banks would
also not be paid.”[26]
This makes trade between Ukraine and Russia
impossible to continue. Evidently Ukraine’s
authorities had received assurance from IMF and U.S.
officials that no real “good faith” bargaining would
be required to gain ongoing support. Ukraine’s
Parliament did not even find it necessary to enact
the new tax code and budget conditionalities that
the IMF loan had demanded.
The
world is now at war financially, and all that seems
to matter is whether, as U.S. Defense Secretary
Donald Rumsfeld had put matters, “you are for us or
against us.” As President Putin remarked at the 70th
session of the UN General Assembly regarding
America’s support of Al Qaeda, Al Nusra and other
allegedly “moderate” ISIS allies in Syria: “I cannot
help asking those who have caused this situation: Do
you realize now what you have done? … I am afraid
the question will hang in the air, because policies
based on self-confidence and belief in one’s
exceptionality and impunity have never been
abandoned.”[27]
The blowback
America’s unilateralist geopolitics are tearing up
the world’s economic linkages that were put in place
in the heady days after World War II, when Europe
and other countries were so disillusioned that they
believed the United States was acting out of
idealism rather than national self-interest. Today
the question is how long Western Europe will be
willing to forego its trade and investment interests
by accepting U.S.-sponsored sanctions against
Russia, Iran and other economies. Germany, Italy and
France already are feeling the strains.
The oil and
pipeline war designed to bypass Russian energy
exports is flooding Europe with refugees, as well as
spreading terrorism. Although the leading issue in
America’s Republican presidential debate on December
15, 2015, was safety from Islamic jihadists, no
candidate thought to explain the source of this
terrorism in America’s alliance with Wahabist Saudi
Arabia and Qatar, and hence with Al Qaeda and
ISIS/Daish as a means of destabilizing secular
regimes in Libya, Iraq, Syria, and earlier in
Afghanistan. Going back to the original sin of CIA
hubris – overthrowing the secular Iranian Prime
Minister leader Mohammad Mosaddegh in 1953 – U.S.
foreign policy has been based on the assumption that
secular regimes tend to be nationalist and resist
privatization and neoliberal austerity.
Based on
this assumption, U.S. Cold Warriors have aligned
themselves against democratic regimes seeking to
promote their own prosperity and resist
neoliberalism in favor of maintaining their own
traditional mixed public/private economies. That is
the back-story of the U.S. fight to control the rest
of the world. Tearing apart the IMF’s rules is only
the most recent chapter. Arena by arena, the core
values of what used to be American and European
social democratic ideology are being uprooted by the
tactics being used to hurt Russia, China and their
prospective Eurasian allies.
The
Enlightenment’s ideals were of secular democracy and
the rule of international law applied equally to all
nations, classical free market theory (of markets
free from unearned income and rent extraction by
special interests), and public investment in
infrastructure to hold down the cost of living and
doing business. These are all now to be sacrificed
to a militant U.S. unilateralism. Putting their
“indispensable nation” above the rule of law and
parity of national interests (the 1648 Westphalia
treaty, not to mention the Geneva Convention and
Nuremburg laws), U.S. neocons proclaim that
America’s destiny is to prevent foreign secular
democracy from acting in ways other than in
submission to U.S. diplomacy. Behind this lie the
special U.S. financial and corporate interests that
control American foreign policy.
This is not
how the Enlightenment was supposed to turn out.
Industrial capitalism a century ago was expected to
evolve into an economy of abundance worldwide.
Instead, we have American Pentagon capitalism, with
financial bubbles deteriorating into a polarized
rentier economy and a resurgence of old-fashioned
imperialism. If and when a break comes, it will not
be marginal but a seismic geopolitical shift.
The Dollar Bloc’s Financial Curtain
By treating Ukraine’s repudiation of its official
debt to Russia’s National Wealth Fund as the new
norm, the IMF has blessed its default. President
Putin and foreign minister Lavrov have said that
they will sue in British courts. The open question
is whether any court exist in the West not under the
thumb of U.S. veto?
America’s
New Cold War maneuvering has shown that the two
Bretton Woods institutions are unreformable. It is
easier to create new institutions such as the AIIB
than to retrofit the IMF and World Bank, NATO and
behind it, the dollar standard – all burdened with
the legacy of their vested interests.
U.S.
geostrategists evidently thought that excluding
Russia, China and other Eurasian countries from the
U.S.-based financial and trade system would isolate
them in a similar economic box to Cuba, Iran and
other sanctioned adversaries. The idea was to force
countries to choose between being impoverished by
such exclusion, or acquiescing in U.S. neoliberal
drives to financialize their economies under U.S.
control.
What is
lacking here is the idea of critical mass. The
United States may arm-twist Europe to impose trade
and financial sanctions on Russia, and may use the
IMF and World Bank to exclude countries not under
U.S. hegemony from participating in dollarized
global trade and finance. But this diplomatic action
is producing an equal and opposite reaction. That is
the Newtonian law of geopolitics. It is propelling
other countries to survive by avoiding demands to
impose austerity on their government budgets and
labor, by creating their own international financial
organization as an alternative to the IMF, and by
juxtaposing their own “aid” lending to that of the
U.S.-centered World Bank.
This
blowback requires an international court to handle
disputes free from U.S. arm-twisting. The Eurasian
Economic Union accordingly has created its own court
to adjudicate disputes. This may provide an
alternative to Judge Griesa’s New York federal
kangaroo court ruling in favor of vulture funds
derailing Argentina’s debt settlements and excluding
that country from world financial markets.
The more
nakedly self-serving U.S. policy is – from backing
radical fundamentalist outgrowths of Al Qaeda
throughout the Near East to right-wing nationalists
in Ukraine and the Baltics – then the greater the
pressure will grow for the Shanghai Cooperation
Organization, AIIB and related institutions to break
free of the post-1945 Bretton Woods system run by
the U.S. State, Defense and Treasury Departments and
their NATO superstructure of coercive military
bases. As Paul Craig Roberts recently summarized the
dynamic, we are back with George Orwell’s 1984
global fracture between Oceania (the United States,
Britain and its northern European NATO allies as the
sea and air power) vs. Eurasia as the consolidated
land power.
Footnotes:
http://michael-hudson.com/ |