How Two-Party
Political Systems Bolster Capitalism
By Richard Wolff
February 02, 2016 "Information
Clearing House"
- Mainstream economics has always privileged one
debate above all others as its most central. Should
production and distribution of goods and services be
private or public, done by individuals or the state?
Mainstream economists likewise keep aggressively
projecting this question as the central
debate for politics and politicians. Such arrogant
self-confidence is the other side of the insular
self-absorption that characterizes so much of the
mainstream economics "discipline."
To reproduce
capitalism is to continue the existence of that
particular economic system.
On one side of the debate are devotees of (1)
private ownership of productive resources and (2)
market exchanges to connect the private owners with
one another and everyone else. They believe that
private property and markets best serve every
society's economic interests - growth, efficiency,
fairness and rising mass consumption. On the other
side are devotees of government economic
intervention to correct, moderate or offset the many
flaws and weaknesses they find in private property
and markets. They believe that society's best
economic interests can only be served through such
an intervention. Most people interested in economics
and politics have long accepted (been trapped
within?) these mainstream positions as the
boundaries of economic thought, research and policy.
However, a much deeper level of discussion about the
intersection of politics and economics exists. It
concerns economic issues ignored by the mainstream,
and questions not raised but rather swept under
ideological rugs. Mainstream debates in political
economy conceal more than they illuminate. They
never explore the complex relation between
contemporary politics and the reproduction of
the capitalist economic system versus transition
to alternatives.
To reproduce capitalism is to continue the existence
of that particular economic system. By capitalist
system, we mean primarily the organization of work
around the relationship of employer to employee (a
relationship different from that of master to slave
or lord to serf in the slave and feudal systems that
often preceded modern capitalism).
Effects of the
Two-Party System
For the reproduction of capitalism, the
two-major-party structure dominating politics has
proven very effective in most nations for some time
now. While party names vary, their common
relationship to reproducing capitalism does not.
Examples include the Republicans and Democrats in
the United States, Conservatives and Labour in the
United Kingdom, Christian Democrats and Socialists
in Germany, and so on. All those parties implicitly
endorse and support the reproduction of capitalism,
and most do so explicitly as well. The first in each
pair differs from the second only on which variant
of capitalism they prefer.
No matter
which party prevails, factories, offices and stores
continue to display the same basic employer-employee
organization.
Usually, one party tilts toward a more inclusive and
less unequal variant. It advocates government
intervention to secure that variant. The other party
tilts more toward markets and existing distributions
of private property functioning with strictly
limited government economic interventions. The
winning party adjusts government economic
interventions accordingly to alter the social mix of
private and state enterprises, redistribute income
and wealth toward more or less economic and social
inequality, and so on. No matter which party
prevails, factories, offices and stores - whether
private or state enterprises, whether more or less
taxed and regulated - continue to display the same
basic employer-employee organization.
The avoidance of any explicit discussion, debate or
focus on alternative enterprise organizations serves
to hide how both parties support the capitalist mode
of enterprise organization. In the laws they pass;
the administrative rules they enforce; the cultural
meanings they constantly presume, endorse and
reinforce for mass media, schools etc., both parties
cement the social dominance of the employer-employee
relationship that structures capitalist enterprises.
They function as if that relationship were the best
humanly possible, agreed universally to be such and
thus beyond debate
This two-major-party arrangement both allows for
disagreements yet also keeps dissent bounded by
common commitments to reproduce capitalism. Popular
disaffection from one party's rule usually flows
smoothly into support for the other. Passing
government back and forth between the parties makes
the enduring capitalist system appear to be above
the fray, beyond political dispute, forever.
Meanwhile ideologues, academic and otherwise,
endlessly reaffirm capitalism as the best possible
economic system for humans: something only ignorance
or evil would contest or even question. When
politics then focuses on other social issues (for
example, tax rates, civil liberties, immigration,
marriage equality, austerity policies, climate
change, school curricula, and so on), their intimate
connection to the needs and pressures of a
capitalist economic system is lost or minimized. How
an alternative structure of enterprises might help
address those social issues in other and better ways
is excluded from political debate and struggle.
Sometimes individuals and groups develop public
positions that take tentative steps toward
questioning capitalism's reproduction. This usually
happens when its instabilities (e.g. business
cycles), inequalities (in wealth, income, political
power, cultural access), and/or social injustices
focus attention on economic policies amid
deteriorating economic conditions. In recent times,
the crash of 2008, corporate bailouts, austerity
policies (or, more broadly, neoliberalism) and
widening gaps between rich and poor have provoked
oppositions to such policies and conditions. Some
within those oppositions reason their way toward
identifying capitalism as the systemic problem to be
solved. But the "socialism" they sometimes promote
as an alternative to capitalism usually turns out
not to involve any basic change in the organization
of enterprises. They remain trapped in the old
debate between more or less government intervention,
private versus state enterprises etc.
The
Suppression of Third-Party Challengers
When neither major party adequately addresses an
issue important to significant communities,
additional parties grow and/or newly emerge into
political importance. Recent examples include Green
parties, anti-austerity parties, regional parties
(e.g. in Scotland, Catalonia etc.) and new or
resurging nationalist, anti-immigration and
quasi-fascist parties (e.g. France and central
Europe). While attacking the two-party system around
their issues of chief concern, such parties rarely
recognize, question or criticize that system's
support for capitalism's reproduction (despite
occasional anti-capitalist rhetoric).
The two parties' procedures to marginalize or
suppress oppositional individuals, groups and new
small parties often - but not always - succeed.
Recently, failures occurred in elections in Greece,
Portugal and Spain: The long dominant two mainstream
parties suffered major losses. Government no longer
passed between them but instead to different parties
or coalitions formerly marginalized or just
emerging. In France, the same outcome almost
occurred in 2015 and may yet be achieved.
Electoral dominance lost by the traditional
two-party political system followed in each case
from mounting mass opposition to austerity policies
and the inequalities they both reflect and
reinforce. Three major questions now confront the
newly empowered parties and coalitions: (1) Will
they sustain their oppositions to austerity and
deepening inequalities? (2) Will their oppositions
succeed? and (3) If austerity and inequalities
persist, what will happen? Will party members and
leaders then go beyond those oppositions? Will they
become a party opposing the reproduction of
capitalism and advocating an alternative economic
system that includes non-capitalist organizations of
enterprises?
Tentative movement in that direction has become
visible. In the United States, Occupy Wall Street
and then Bernie Sanders have explicitly endorsed
worker cooperatives. However vague and undeveloped,
such programmatic support for co-ops is an implicit
critique of capitalist organizations of enterprise
and advocacy of an alternative. The same applies,
for example, to the growing global interest in
Spain's cooperatively owned Mondragon Corporation,
Italy's large and vibrant co-op system, the
occupations of factories in Argentina and the
growing co-op community in the United States.
Marxist, socialist and other left groups are
recognizing slowly that co-ops represent a seriously
underappreciated alternative to capitalist
organizations of enterprises. That recognition
enables a rethinking of strategies for social change
with new political alliances and programs.
The economics of our politics is deepening. It is no
longer totally trapped in the tedious old debate
over private versus public ownership, and markets
versus planning. The 20th century was obsessed with
what were two parallel forms of that debate: (1)
"capitalism versus socialism" and (2) neoclassical
versus Keynesian economics. That obsession is
dissolving in the 21st century.
Instead, the economic issue now
emerging is about the relationships we want among us
at work, in the enterprises where we spend so huge a
portion of our adult lives. Will they remain
capitalism's hierarchical, undemocratic
relationships of boss to underlings in factories,
offices and stores? Or will we shift politics to a
social debate and struggle over democratizing our
enterprises and thereby our economy? Will
democratically organized cooperative workplaces
collaborate with similarly organized residential
communities to move society toward the liberty,
equality and fraternity that capitalism always
promised but never delivered?
Richard D.
Wolff is Professor of Economics Emeritus, University
of Massachusetts, Amherst where he taught economics
from 1973 to 2008. He is currently a Visiting
Professor in the Graduate
Program in International Affairs of the New
School University, New York City. He also teaches
classes regularly at the
Brecht Forum
in Manhattan.
Visit Professor Wolff's social movement project,
democracyatwork.info.
This article originally appeared at
Truthout.org. |