How Debt
Conquered America
Special Report: America presents itself to the world
as “the land of the free” but – for the vast
majority – it is a place of enslaving indebtedness,
a reality for much of “the 99%” that has deep
historical roots hidden or “lost” from our history,
as Jada Thacker explains.
By Jada Thacker
Since its
center-stage debut during the Occupy Wall Street
movement, “the 99%” – a term emblematic of extreme
economic inequality confronting the vast majority –
has become common place. The term was coined by
sociology professor David Graeber, an Occupy leader
and author of the encyclopedic Debt: The First
5,000 Years, published just as the Occupy
movement captured headlines.
What
Graeber’s monumental work did not emphasize
specifically, and what most Americans still do not
appreciate, is how debt was wielded as the weapon of
choice to subjugate the 99% in the centuries before
the Occupy protesters popularized the term. Like so
many aspects of our Lost History, the legacy of debt
has been airbrushed from our history texts, but not
from our lives.
The
original 99% in America did not occupy Wall Street
in protest. They occupied the entire Western
Hemisphere as original inhabitants of North and
South America. After 20,000 years of Occupy
Hemisphere, an Italian entrepreneur appeared, having
pitched an investment opportunity to his financial
backers in Spain.
Soon after
Columbus launched his business enterprise on the
pristine beaches of the New World, each native
discovered there above the age of puberty was
required to remit a “hawk’s bell’s worth” of gold
dust to the Spaniards every two weeks. The hands of
all those failing to do so were cut off and strung
about their necks – so that they bled to death, thus
motivating the compliance of others.
Bartolome
de las Casas, a contemporary slave-owning
priest-turned-reformer, reported three million
natives were exterminated by Spanish
entrepreneurship in only 15 years. His population
figures were guesstimates, but modern researchers
confirm that 80 to 90% of the Taino people in the
Hispaniola-Cuba region died within 30 years of
Spanish contact, the majority from disease.
In the
century following Hernan Cortés’s extreme “hostile
takeover” of the admittedly brutal Aztec regime
(1519-21) the native population of the entire region
also declined by 90%. The same story generally
followed the Spanish march across Central and South
America.
Spanish
conquistadors rationalized that their colonial
business model, however brutal, was morally
necessary: without religious conversion to the
Church, pagan natives would have been condemned to
an everlasting Christian hell. Ostensibly to save
pagan souls, Spaniards destroyed pagan persons with
the draconian encomienda system, in essence
a debt-based protection racket.
The
encomienda dated from the Roman occupation of
Iberia (Spain), but had more recently metastasized
from the practice of Christians exacting tribute
from Muslims during the so-called Spanish
Reconquista, which ended the year Columbus
sailed. Under this medieval debt obligation, the
native 99% were deemed to owe their labor and
resources (not their land, which was expropriated by
the Crown) to Spaniards in exchange for “protection”
and religious education.
The
system’s legitimacy in the New World depended upon
the useful fiction that the native labor force was
not composed of sentient human beings. Thus, it was
not lawful to impose encomienda upon
persons of mixed-race (mestizo) presumably because
they had enough European blood to be considered
human.
In
practice, this debt-labor system devolved into
slavery and butchery of the most brutal sort
imaginable, as witnessed by de las Casas. Though the
encomienda was eventually abolished, it was
replaced only by the hacienda system.
Haciendas were Spanish
plantations on which natives worked as landless
peasants, who owed a share of their produce to the
landowner for the privilege of living lives similar
only to those of Southern plantation slaves in the
U.S. a century or two hence.
Spanish
mines were the scene of even worse atrocities. In
The Open Veins of Latin America, Eduardo
Galeano details the horrors: native mothers in the
notorious Bolivian Potosi silver mine murdered their
own children to save them from lives spent as slave
troglodytes.
Although
some Potosi miners were nominally “free” laborers,
they worked under a debt-peonage system that forbade
them to leave the mine while still indebted to
employers who loaned them the tools of their trade.
Not even death extinguished their debt: upon the
death of the indebted miner, his family was required
to repay the debt with their own
perpetually-indebted labor.
The tragedy
of the Spaniards’ devastation of untold millions of
native lives was compounded by seven million African
slaves who died during the process of their
enslavement. Another 11 million died as New World
slaves thereafter.
The Spanish
exploitation of land and labor continued for over
three centuries until the Bolivarian revolutions of
the Nineteenth Century. But even afterward, the
looting continued for another century to benefit
domestic oligarchs and foreign businesses interests,
including those of U.S. entrepreneurs.
Possibly
the only other manmade disasters as irredeemable as
the Spanish Conquest – in terms of loss of life,
destruction and theft of property, and
impoverishment of culture – were the Mongol
invasions of the Thirteenth and Fourteenth
centuries. The Mongols and the Spaniards each
inflicted a human catastrophe fully comparable to
that of a modern, region-wide thermonuclear war.
The
North American Business Model
Unlike
Spaniards, Anglo-American colonists brought their
own working-class labor from Europe. While ethnic
Spaniards remained at the apex of the Latin American
economic pyramid, that pyramid in North America
would be built largely from European ethnic stock.
Conquered natives were to be wholly excluded from
the structure.
While
contemporary North Americans look back at the
Spanish Conquest with self-righteous horror, most do
not know the majority of the first English settlers
were not even free persons, much less democrats.
They were in fact expiration-dated slaves, known as
indentured servants.
They
commonly served 7 to 14 years of bondage to their
masters before becoming free to pursue independent
livelihoods. This was a cold comfort, indeed, for
the 50% of them who died in bondage within five
years of arriving in Virginia – this according to
American Slavery, American Freedom: The Ordeal
of Colonial Virginia by the dean of American
colonial history, Edmund S. Morgan.
Also
disremembered is that the Jamestown colony was
founded by a corporation, not by the Crown. The
colony was owned by shareholders in the Virginia
Company of London and was intended to be a
profit-making venture for absentee investors. It
never made a profit.
After 15
years of steady losses, Virginia’s corporate
investors bailed out, abandoning the colonists to a
cruel fate in a pestilential swamp amidst
increasingly hostile natives. Jamestown’s masters
and servants alike survived only because they were
rescued by the Crown, which was less motivated by
Christian mercy than by the tax it was collecting on
each pound of the tobacco the colonists exported to
England.
Thus a
failed corporate start-up survived only as a
successful government-sponsored oligarchy, which was
economically dependent upon the export of addictive
substances produced by indentured and slave labor.
This was the debt-genesis of American-Anglo
colonization, not smarmy fairy tales featuring
Squanto or Pocahontas, or actor Ronald Reagan’s
fantasized (and plagiarized) “shining city upon a
hill.”
While the
Spaniard’s ultimate goal was to command native labor
from the economic apex, the Anglo-American empire
would replace native labor with its own
disadvantaged 99%. The ultimate goal of Anglo
colonization was not intended so much to put the
natives under the lash as to have rid of them
altogether.
Trade
deficits and slavery would answer their purpose
quite nicely. By the 1670s New England Puritans were
already rigging the wampum market at their
trading posts in order to pressure the Wampanoag
into ceding land – thus in part precipitating the
Narragansett War, King Philip’s War, the ensuing
genocide of some natives, and the mass enslavement
of others to be sold abroad.
As
chronicled by Alan Gallay in The Indian Slave
Trade: The Rise of the English Empire in the
American South, 1670-1717, Carolina colonists
concurrently sold Indian slaves to the God-fearing
Puritans – and trading others for African slaves at
a 2:1 exchange rate – while wielding trading-post
debt against local Indians, precipitating the
Yamasee War which proved to be a major disaster for
natives and whites alike.
For half a
century, the Carolina colonists’ export of tens of
thousands of Indian slaves exceeded imports of black
slaves. This was the origin of Southern plantation
agriculture.
The
institution of North American Indian slavery was
necessarily based upon debt. English law forbade
colonists from enslaving free persons, but it
conceded that prisoners of war could be considered
slaves. Because captives owed their lives to their
captors, the latter could dispose of the debt as
they saw fit, to include transferring the debt to a
third party for goods and services.
The
captive-to-slave pipeline was sanctioned by none
other than John Locke, the renowned philosopher who
directly inspired Jefferson’s composition of the
Declaration of Independence, and who is often
championed today by libertarians – and no wonder! –
as an oracle of private property rights.
All along
the westward frontier, American colonists continued
to foreclose on natives’ land with debt machinations
perhaps less overtly brutal, but far more devious
than the Spanish encomienda: to remove the
self-reliant 99% from their land, it was necessary
first to remove their self-reliance.
Here is how
President Thomas Jefferson explained the process to
future president William Henry Harrison in 1803: “To
promote this disposition to exchange lands […] we
shall push our trading uses, and be glad to see the
good and influential individuals among them run in
debt, because we observe that when these debts get
beyond what the individuals can pay, they become
willing to lop them off by a cession of lands. …
“As to
their fear, we presume that our strength and their
weakness is now so visible that they must see we
have only to shut our hand to crush them, and that
all our liberalities to them proceed from motives of
pure humanity only. Should any tribe be foolhardy
enough to take up the hatchet at any time, the
seizing the whole country of that tribe, and driving
them across the Mississippi, as the only condition
of peace, would be an example to others, and a
furtherance of our final consolidation.”
Debt – more
so than firepower, firewater, or even disease –
provided the economic weapon by which
Anglo-Americans designed to privatize the Indians’
means of self-reliance. “How the West Was Won” in
the “Land of the Free” was a saga of debt moving
inexorably westward in what Jefferson called “our
final consolidation.” He might well have said “final
solution,” but he did not.
As debt
expanded westward, desperate Anglo settlers believed
the frontier land was “free for the taking” for
those with the stamina to seize it. This belief
ultimately proved illusory, as land “squatters” and
homesteaders were evicted or forced into paid
tenancy through debt or the legal maneuvering of
wealthy land speculators.
George
Washington secured the eviction of pioneer families
from western Pennsylvania land he claimed to own in
absentia, although those he forced from the land
possessed a deed that pre-dated his own, as related
in Joel Achenbach’s The Grand Idea: George
Washington’s Potomac & the Race to the West.
On the
other hand, Daniel Boone, famed for leading pioneers
westward through the Cumberland Gap, died landless,
all his land claims having been picked off by legal
sharpshooters. Also landless, Davy Crockett died at
the Alamo in an attempt to secure Texas acreage he
never survived to claim.
The final
illusion of free soil vaporized when in 1890 the
United States census declared the American Frontier
closed. Much of what was left had at any rate been
monopolized by railroad, ranching, mining, and
forestry corporations after the Dawes Act had
privatized most of the natives’ “protected”
reservation lands in 1887. For most white and black
Americans, meanwhile, free tenancy homesteads had
never materialized in the first place.
Debt vs. Self Reliance
Jefferson’s
“final consolidation” was accomplished by a system
he admitted offered debt with one hand but held a
sword in the other. The estimated 3,000,000 families
who lost their homes during the Great Recession that
began in 2007 understand this principle intimately.
The debt
system is in fact more powerful in the Twenty-first
Century than ever before because the 99% are far
less self-reliant now than ever before. To
understand why this is so, we must first think
seriously about the term “self-reliance.”
Although we
may casually refer to someone as being self-reliant,
such people do not actually exist. Human beings
simply are not equipped to survive, much less
prosper, strictly as self-reliant individuals. As
infants and children we cannot survive without
familial care, and as adults we cannot prosper
without the cooperation and support of peers.
There has
never been, and never will be, such a thing as a
“self-made man.”
On the
other hand, the 99% was self-reliant the day before
Columbus arrived. They possessed the means of
production of the energy and food resources needed
for their group’s long-term survival and biological
propagation, all without significant contact with
others. Had the culture of Columbus been equally
self-reliant, he would never have needed to set
sail.
Judged by
modern standards, American native groups were
intensely cooperative, extremely egalitarian, and
inherently (if informally) democratic. Government as
a coercive force did not exist in these groups as we
know it today, though leadership and traditional
mores were vital to group survival.
Similarly,
the concepts of money and monetary debt were
unknown, as was the concept of an economic “class”
that reserved economic privileges or property to
itself at the expense of all. Interpersonal behavior
within native groups, by eyewitness accounts, was
respectful and peaceful.
Behavior
between native groups usually was not
peaceful. Persistent low-level warfare was the norm.
It could be brutal indeed, but rarely if ever rose
to the scale of civilized “total war.”
Indeed,
since a “warrior class” did not exist and could not
be conscripted, native combatants were necessarily
volunteers who otherwise were needed at home to help
provide for their families. Consequently, the
severity and duration of native warfare were limited
– as it is for all human groups everywhere – to what
society at large can economically afford.
Among the
original 99%, all men mostly performed the same sort
of occupational tasks. All women did the same. Both
sexes had a common goal: food production and the
reproduction and rearing of children. While all
human groups must achieve these basic goals,
civilized peoples do so within a complex
hierarchical labor system, wherein some occupational
tasks are considered more worthy than others and are
compensated accordingly.
Civilized
division of labor inevitably has metamorphosed into
a hierarchy of economic classes, ultimately
resulting in the private ownership of the means of
production by the “haves” and the lack of private
ownership by the “have-nots.” This was unknown in
uncivilized native society.
Native
land, for example, was not actually “owned” in the
contemporary sense at all. Natives were acutely
aware that they, themselves, were products of the
land; for them, claiming ownership of the land would
have made as much sense as children claiming
ownership of parents.
This is not
to say that natives were not territorial, for they
were highly territorial. But their territoriality
was not based upon legalistic titles of private
property. Access to communally-held food resources –
not ownership of real estate – was their sine
qua non for sustainable survival.
What
natives shared in common they defended in common.
Having no economic hierarchy, no one in their
society could control the food supply of others,
simply because no individual could claim exclusive
ownership of the collective means of food
production. Abundant resources were therefore
abundant for all; if scarce, they were scarce for
all.
True
enough, when the Europeans arrived, they found
native societies everywhere in conflict with their
neighbors, but nowhere did they find endemic
poverty, famine, disease or social degeneracy.
Indeed, it was the self-reliant natives who helped
feed the first generation of starvation-prone
English colonists both at Jamestown and at Plymouth.
Once
private ownership clamped down upon the landscape,
virtually nobody would control their own food supply
without some form of indebtedness to another. But
since the resource stock of self-reliant food
production – the land itself – would remain in
place, private monopolist-owners required an
economic mechanism to keep what remained
within their grasp forever out of reach of others.
The
Hand That Gives
As
self-reliant native societies were decimated by
debt, disease, and sword, ownership of the
previously un-owned land was usurped by the
conquerors. But it was not to be usurped equally by
all of them.
Economic-class domination was problematical in
British North America, because the economic pyramid
that supplanted the communal native system was
composed largely by people in the same Anglo ethnic
group. It is one thing to justify violent economic
domination of those with a “foreign” language,
culture, religious sensibility and physical
appearance; it is quite another to justify
overlord-ship of those virtually indistinguishable
from oneself.
Nevertheless, class domination was a stark fact of
life in Colonial America where the economic division
between masters and servants was sharp and where all
land titles originally flowed down from the Crown to
a short list of royal favorites, sycophants and
lackeys. After the Revolution, however, maintaining
economic class domination proved especially tricky,
eventually requiring the drafting of an
“all-American” document for that specific purpose.
Yet the
solution to the problem to elite domination of a
supposed “republic” had been imported, disease-like,
from the Old World. In the centuries preceding
Columbus’s arrival, two critical economic
developments had transpired in Europe: the rise of
an economy based upon metallic currency and the de
facto repeal of the Biblical prohibition on loaning
currency at interest.
The upshot
of these quiet revolutions was the replacement of
the sovereign currency owned by kings and emperors
by that of private currency owned by the new
economic elite known as bankers. In Antiquity,
currency was owed by subjects to the
monarch as tax. This was the reason for Joseph and
Mary’s celebrated journey to Bethlehem.
But by the
time of Columbus (and continuing to the present day)
currency was to be owed to private persons by
the monarch, who borrowed from them at interest to
finance wars to protect and defend monarchical
control over the means of food production.
To be sure,
government still levied taxes as in the days of
Jesus, but the tax revenue was not exchanged
directly to conduct war, but to repay principal and
interest to bankers only too obliging to finance
wars for personal gain.
Indeed, war
and bank-indebted sovereigns are inseparable. The
very first European bank to loan at interest was
established during The Crusades by the Knights
Templar; Spanish king Charles I squandered the vast
majority of his conquistadors’ New World gold on
paying crushing interest charges incurred during his
long war in the Netherlands; King William’s War
against France was made possible by the
establishment in 1694 of the Bank of England, the
world’s first central bank.
Wherever
modern war exists, governments are indebted to
bankers. This is what prompted a cash-strapped
Napoleon to observe: “When a government is dependent
upon bankers for money, they and not the leaders of
the government control the situation, since the hand
that gives is above the hand that takes. Money has
no motherland; financiers are without patriotism and
without decency; their sole object is gain.”
It is
hardly coincidental that the first bank in North
America was chartered to supply arms for the
American Revolution, and the first central bank of
the United States was chartered specifically to fund
Revolutionary War debt. Although no banks had
existed in British North America during the 174
years preceding the Declaration of Independence,
America’s first commercial bank sprang forth in
1781, literally before the smoke had cleared from
the American Revolution – nearly a decade ahead of
Constitutional government.
This fact
alone suggests where real economic power had been
vested, long before the words “We the People” ever
went to press.
Unlike the
days of Antiquity, wealth taken by force was not to
be held by those who wielded the sword, but by those
who financed the supply of swords. The means of
North American food production, first expropriated
under the banner of European imperial power, would
be owned thereafter – in Republican America as in
monarchical Europe alike – by new conquistadors
called creditors.
Scarcity, Debt, and “Necessitous Men”
Monopoly of
the food supply of the 99% was accomplished by
replacing self-reliance with debt bondage. The
second step was to reserve private land ownership to
particular individuals within the dominant
class. This would be accomplished by imposing upon
the land a wholly arbitrary number called a “price.”
The prime
function of a monetary price was to render land
unaffordable – for all except a few
creditor-entrepreneurs. Under the
precious-metal-based system then in place, currency
had been endemically scarce in North America, making
this an easy task.
If American
land – so recently filched from its native
inhabitants, then re-filched from its imperial
British overlords – were to be had by freedom-loving
American common folk, it would be had on credit, and
on the creditor’s terms. The fate of the Ohio land
of the Old Northwest Territory provides a case in
point.
In 1749,
King George II granted Ohio land to a private
corporation, the Ohio Land Company, whose
shareholders included George Washington’s paternal
uncles. Tellingly, the grant was bestowed 15 years
before Britain actually established sovereignty over
that land by winning the French and Indian War.
That war –
which became the first World War in all of human
history – was ignited, not incidentally, by George
Washington himself when he ordered the murder of
Indians and a French nobleman upon Ohio land
Washington likely considered private property,
possibly his own.
It would
yet require the American Revolution, three more
Indian Wars – all under Washington’s presidential
authority – plus a good deal of diplomatic
treachery, finally to “open” the land for Anglo
settlement.
But its
first owners were not to be hardy frontiersmen and
their growing families. In the meantime, select
government committees, again not incidentally, had
priced the land out of reach of those most in need,
so ownership fell into the hands of well-heeled real
estate speculators, to include of course Washington,
himself.
With the
Ohio land grab as background, let us consider the
principle of scarcity as it relates to trade. All
trade is predicated upon exchanging something one
possesses for something one would prefer to possess
instead. If there were no such thing as scarcity –
that is, if all persons already possessed sufficient
quantities of the stuff they need – nobody would
have the inclination to trade anything at all.
What, then,
about debt? No self-regarding person would
voluntarily borrow currency at interest if they
already possessed enough currency to exchange for
the stuff they need to live. If this is so, then for
creditors to profit by lending at interest, a single
condition is always necessary: persons should
not be allowed a sufficient quantity of
currency to complete the desired exchange. When
currency is scarcer than the goods for which it is
to be exchanged, prospective buyers have only two
legal options: do without, or borrow.
If the
consequences of doing without (starvation or
homelessness, for example) are sufficiently
unacceptable, and if a creditor is available, then a
debtor is certain to emerge. This emphatically does
not imply that the debtor is always a willing party
to a debt obligation.
Indeed, the
entire logic of indebtedness implies the opposite.
No rational entities – businesses, governments,
or individual persons – put themselves into
interest-bearing debt if they need not do so.
Put simply: debtors are the needy who can no longer
afford self-reliance.
Franklin
Delano Roosevelt expressed this reality eloquently
in 1944 when he declared to the nation, “Necessitous
men are not free men.” He was mostly preaching to
the choir. The American 99% had known this truth
since indentured-servant pioneers had waded ashore
at Jamestown in 1607 – only to find upon their
emancipation that all the valuable land had already
been monopolized by the planter elite.
Having
failed to learn the history debt played in the
exploitation of the New World, modern Americans fail
to perceive they have inherited the same debt-system
foisted upon the natives by colonizing Europeans –
and later by American elites upon their own people.
Consequently, we think of debt only as a contract
made voluntarily between two consenting adults.
But in
America today every newborn child is a predestined
debtor, no matter what he or she will consent to in
the future. Once the free land tenure of communal
native societies was destroyed, it was never to
return, not even for the progeny of the destroyers.
Debt-bondage today takes a more subtle form. If
Americans are no longer debt-peons, forced to slave
away on the landlord’s estate or starve, it is only
because the landlords no longer care where we slave
away. Landlords extract their monthly payments
regardless. Today about 25% or more of the earnings
of workers flows as rent to landlords or as debt
payments to mortgagees.
Indeed,
fully half of the debts held by commercial banks
alone are tied to real estate. Nor do Americans
conceive the staggering price tag affixed to land:
for example, economist Michael Hudson reports the
dollar valuation of real estate in New York City
alone is higher than that of the industrial plant of
the entire nation.
As 2016
arrived, American households owed about $13.8
trillion in home mortgage debt, which effectively is
a rent payment to the mortgagee who holds the title
to the property. All persons without a mortgage must
pay rent to a landlord. All persons without
mortgages or landlords must still pay property taxes
until death, at which time any unpaid taxes – in an
echo of the Potosi miners’ debt-peonage system –
must be paid by their indebted heirs.
Thus, the
entire landmass of the Western Hemisphere, which for
over 20,000 years had been the source of
self-reliance for all its human inhabitants, remains
hostage to the same debt system that seized it and
which now extracts ransom from the 99% who would
claim the least corner of it as home.
Debt vs. Dollars
In Early
America, the scarcity of precious-metal coinage
(specie) was a perennial problem. So scarce was gold
that the first coinage act passed by Congress in
1792 defined the U.S. dollar as “each to be the
value of a Spanish milled dollar as the same is now
current, and to contain … four hundred and sixteen
grains of standard silver.”
Thus the
United States dollar was literally established on a
“silver standard,” and it was Spanish silver at
that! The now oft fetishized American “gold
standard” for currency would not officially
materialize until the Twentieth Century with the
passage of the Gold Standard Act in 1900. It did not
last long.
After only
33 years, the Gold Standard was abandoned by the
Emergency Banking Act of 1933, which was passed to
remedy – what else? – the scarcity of currency
during the Great Depression. (All the world’s major
currencies dropped the gold standard during this
crisis.)
Subsequently, the gold standard never was reemployed
domestically in the U.S. And even the dollar’s
international convertibility to gold finally was
declared extinct, courtesy of President Richard
Nixon, in 1971.
It was
appropriate for gold to tread the path of the
dinosaur, for it had come to resemble one. Though it
is evident that currency must be scarce to some
degree in order to maintain its exchange-value
purchasing power, all precious-metal-backed
currencies suffer from their dinosaur-like tendency
of becoming increasingly scarce.
As the
volume of trade increases in a growing economy, any
medium of exchange based upon a finite quantity of
metal cannot keep pace. The result is a constant
increase in the purchasing power of the metal-backed
currency, which becomes ever-more scarce in
proportion to the number of persons needing to
possess it.
This, in
turn, leads to “necessitous men” becoming debtors to
those in possession of the metal – sometimes to
governments, sometimes to businessmen, but always to
bankers.
Historically, American currency has usually
consisted of a mish-mash of specie, paper money, and
debt, often accompanied by copious reserves of
flimflammery. Thus, purchasing power has always been
based partially upon some form of debt obligation,
not just gold or silver coin.
During the
Colonial Era, “bills of exchange” – essentially IOUs
of transferrable debt – served as currency for the
wealthy and the merchant class. Later, “bills of
credit,” un-backed fiat currency issued by the
Continental Congress as paper money, financed the
Revolution, along with some $60 million of private
domestic lending.
Finally,
under the National Banking Act of 1862, paper
currency issued by national banks was backed by the
amount of federal debt IOUs owned by the bank. This
officially made the most popular medium of exchange
broadly based upon national (war) debt. In addition,
the government spent into existence Greenback fiat
money, which was backed by nothing at all.
When in
1913 the Federal Reserve Bank (the Fed) began
issuing Federal Reserve Notes, they were at first
redeemable either in gold or “lawful money,” but
their redemption was soon cancelled by the Emergency
Banking Act noted above. Since then, all “backed”
currency has been withdrawn from circulation,
leaving Federal Reserve Notes (dollar bills),
exchangeable only for debt owned by the
privately-owned Fed as the sole legal tender of the
United States.
Although
the gold standard is long gone, “necessitous men”
remain. This is not happenstance.
This is the
result of applying the mentality of gold-standard
scarcity to the modern creation of financial debt,
which is but the latest scheme by which the means of
production of food – that is, the vast landscape of
North America – is owned by the few and rented out
to the rest at interest.
“Gold Bug”
libertarians decry the absence of a federal statute
defining the value of a U.S. dollar – but they miss
the point. No doubt the “value” of a dollar matters
a great deal to those who hoard them by the
billions; but dollar “value” is less a concern for
the 99%, who are allowed to earn so few dollars they
are forced to borrow them at interest from the
hoarders.
As it
applies to the 99%, our wages are the source of the
currency we all must possess in order to live. But
none of us actually controls how much currency we
earn (or quite often how much of it we must spend);
as a result, we do not control how much we may be
forced to borrow.
Finally, we
certainly do not control the conditions that will be
imposed upon us if we must borrow (or whether we
will be allowed to borrow at all). Put bluntly, the
economic lives of wage earners are not in their own
hands, but rest in the “hand that gives.”
We have
only to be thankful we live in a “free country,”
whatever in the world that is supposed to mean.
How
the West Was Owed: Redux
In the
years following the Revolution, some 90% of the
American population subsisted as farmers. American
women in the coming century would, on average, give
birth to eight children who lived into adulthood.
Accordingly, not only did population double every 30
years, the demand for additional farms more than
trebled every generation.
Moreover,
uninformed agricultural practices rapidly destroyed
topsoil, sending “dirt poor” farmers streaming
westward in search of land more fertile than their
wives. As the frontier chased the setting sun,
speculators and corporate agents raced ahead like
locusts, devouring the landscape on the cheap,
renting or re-selling at the price dictated by the
demographics of desperation.
When
American school kids are taught about Conestoga
wagon “prairie schooners” creaking along the Oregon
Trail or the Oklahoma “Sooners” land grab or the
California Gold Rush, they are encouraged to view
these events as technicolor visions of a unique
American Opportunity unavailable to lesser mortals.
In truth,
the 99% headed west simply because there was no
place left for them to go. These economic refugees
no doubt saw opportunity before them, but a great
many of them must have perceived it the same way the
many Third Class passengers on the Titanic viewed
the opportunity offered by a lifeboat with an empty
seat.
In 1893,
historian Frederick Jackson Turner enunciated his
famous “Frontier Thesis.” He claimed that the
American Frontier experience had produced a unique
form of democratic culture, increasingly more
hostile to social and economic hierarchy as it
spread from the Atlantic to the Pacific. The
Frontier Thesis is a powerful idea, especially in
its view of the frontier as an evolutionary process,
which it was.
But
Turner’s thesis perhaps unintentionally reinforced
both the preexisting theocratic Puritanical creed of
American Exceptionalism and the ordained racism of
Manifest Destiny – both of which were based upon a
belief in the sanctity of Anglo-American economic
domination of the New World.
For 40
years, Turner continued to proselytize his prototype
of Hollywood Americanism as the rapidly
industrializing United States rose to world-power
status, and he became a celebrity doing so. Had
Turner spent an hour or two of that time pondering
the deeper implications of his own home mortgage, he
might have discovered a more profound reality.
While the
American frontier had indeed fundamentally and
irrevocably revolutionized the economic relationship
between human beings and their control of the North
American landscape, the revolution was not achieved
by abandoning European principles of social
and economic hierarchy, but by transplanting
them to the Western Hemisphere.
To view the
conquest of North America as the triumphant
flowering of democratic liberty and affluence over
bestial savagery and abject poverty is so factually
vacant, so morally and economically perverse, as to
be considered hallucinatory.
Native
people literally had no words to describe the
cataclysm that had destroyed them. It was left to
follow-on generations of “necessitous men” to learn
the vocabulary of servitude needed to describe their
economic lives.
Here is
only a part of the terminology “necessitous men”
needed to learn: poverty level, payday loans, food
stamps, interest rate, surcharges, eviction,
unemployment rates, lock-outs, foreclosure,
bankruptcy, credit scores, down payment, damage
deposits, credit limit, collection agency,
mortgages, user fees, closing costs, title loans,
bail outs, insolvency, title insurance, origination
fee, installment plans, tax levy, deed restrictions,
market crashes, illiquidity, non-sufficient funds,
minimum payment due, late fees, lay-offs, property
lien, pawn tickets, collateral, tax withholding,
service fees, forfeiture, inflation, deflation,
stagflation…
Is this the
vocabulary of free people?
As of
January, 2016, Americans (government, business and
individuals) owed an estimated $65,000,000,000,000
($65 trillion) in total debt, with the average
citizen’s share about $200,000. Of course, these are
aggregate figures: many individuals and businesses
owe more, many owe less, but everybody
owes.
Now
consider: the annual median income (mid-point, not
the average) of American citizens is $29,000; that
median family savings is below $9,000; and that the
median price of a new home is over $294,000.
Personal debt (not including national and business
debt) per citizen is $54,000, or about twice the
median income.
It does not
require Napoleonic genius to grasp the fact that the
“hand that gives” can load more debt onto the 99%
than they can ever possibly repay. This is not a
mistake or a “conspiracy”; it is simply a business
plan. For every citizen’s $200,000 share of debt,
some other entity or citizen expects to collect
$200,000 plus interest. Will such a business plan
succeed? Ask a Taino or a Wampanoag – if you can
find one handy.
There is an
historical anecdote of a question posed long ago by
a Cherokee. “White Brother,” he said, “when you
first came to this land, there were no debts. There
were no taxes. And our women did all the work. Do
you expect me to believe you can make this situation
better?”
The 99%
should know the answer. And women still do most of
the work.
Jada
Thacker, Ed.D is a Vietnam veteran and author of
Dissecting American History. He teaches
U.S. History at a private institution in Texas.
Contact: jadathacker@sbcglobal.net |