January 21, 2015 "ICH"
- "Of
Two Minds" -
The core dynamic of debt-serfdom is that
debt-serfs must borrow money to buy
essentials while the wealthy borrow
to invest in productive assets.
This is not merely a random result of
free-market capitalism; it is the structure
of cartel-capitalism in which highly
profitable goods and services must be paid
for with highly profitable debt.
This need to borrow to pay for essentials
is already evident in student loans,
vehicles and housing.
The cost of these essentials is so high
that few debt-serfs can borrow enough to pay
for these essentials and then have enough
borrowing power left to buy productive
assets.
Those few who do attempt to buy
productive assets face regulatory hurdles
and costs that limit their ability to own or
launch small-scale profitable enterprises.
The net result is a system in which
the vast majority of productive assets are
owned by the few who then have the means to
exploit the many.
This core dynamic of cartel capitalism
is not new, as longtime correspondent Bart
D. recently observed. This was the core
dynamic at the root of Ireland's
catastrophic potato famine of the 1840s:
wealthy English owned the productive assets
(land) and limited the opportunities for
enterprises that boosted Irish
self-sufficiency and competed with the
assets owned by English financiers and
landed gentry.
Here is Bart's commentary:
I recently picked up a copy of a novel
dealing with the topic of the Irish Potato
famine of 1845-6 from a second hand book
store run by charity. Author is Liam
O’Flaherty and it was written in 1937. It
was re-released in 2002. My edition was
printed in the 1970’s, so it’s had a
following over the years.
Famine
I recommend this book HIGHLY as an
insight into how families, communities,
governments and economics will/are
functioning in impoverished situations now
and in the future. I know this because I was
astonished (not using that word lightly
here) at the similarity in the description
of life and government/business portrayed in
O’Flaherty’s book in 1845 and that which I
have observed closely over many years in
remote Australian Aboriginal communities
from 1994 to 2012.
Especially fascinating to learn that
the English Government provided ‘relief’
loans to Ireland at market interest with a
condition that they could not be used to do
anything productive. Basically they set up a
scheme to pay a small proportion of each
community to build roads, but not a cent
could be spent on developing alternate
Irish-owned industries or businesses for
fear it would upset the rich English
industrialists.
The English imported cheap American
corn meal which everyone was forced to buy
with the English Gov. financed wages
(closing the loop of giving with one hand,
taking with the other and adding in a profit
to boot) after the Irish had to export all
their own grain and livestock to England to
pay the land rents.
The model of resource ownership
described in the novel--English landlords
owned all the Irish peasant farmer land and
set rent at a level that ensured the farmers
remained a hairs breadth ahead of
destitution even under the best of
circumstances--will be, I think, what our
own future will look like. Unfortunately.
It’s very well written and engaging
for the reader, but hard to read because of
its infuriating and tragic subject material.
No happy endings here.
One branch of my family (Scots-Irish,
County Down) immigrated to the U.S. in the
late 1840s, undoubtedly as a result of the
potato famine. This history of exploitation
and financial tyranny is not entirely
abstract to me, and neither is the current
American variation of the debt-serf model.
Those of us with experience in starting
and operating small enterprises know that
dozens of restrictive regulations and
administrative costs limit debt-serfs'
attempts to invest in small-scale productive
ventures. We also know that the Federal
Reserve's free funds for financiers
enables hedge funds to invest $500 million
in the latest software fad, while
small-scale entrepreneurs have no equivalent
conduit to near-zero cost funding.
Globalized cartels eliminate local
pricing power by importing cheap goods from
somewhere else. In less globalized
circumstances, local producers retain some
pricing power (and thus some profitability)
because they can produce goods without the
cost of shipping from overseas.
But the power of cartels buying millions
of units at a time and the low cost of
container shipping means cartels can
eliminate the pricing power of local
small-scale producers virtually everywhere.
Even low-income regions in developing
nations cannot compete with global cartels
in manufactured goods and agricultural/meat
produce.
This is not a random result of free
enterprise; it is the direct result of
central banks' free funds for financiers
that lowers the costs of borrowing and thus
production for cartels.
Debt-serfs may legally start home
businesses in some locales, but as soon as
they become successful enough to compete
with vested interests, their fixed costs are
increased by regulatory and administrative
rules. The resulting erosion of
profitability and the lack of access to
cheap credit limit their ability to expand
without taking on burdensome levels of
costly debt or selling their souls to
vulture capitalists.
At that point, debt-serfs who make the
difficult and risky transition to
small-scale business owners find they have
simply moved to another class of serfdom,
one in which the serfs own an enterprise but
cannot expand their capital. As a result,
small enterprise ends up being just another
version of serfdom, i.e. barely getting
by or borrowing more just to survive.
Consider the evidence of the erosion of
American small business:
Economic Death Spiral: More American
Businesses Dying Than Starting.
The net result is a system in which
the vast majority of productive assets are
owned by the few who then have the means to
exploit the many.