Michael Hudson: The Destiny
of Civilization: Finance Capitalism, Industrial
Capitalism or Socialism?
By Real Progressives
I’d like to introduce our
guest today.
Michael Hudson
is an economist, a professor of economics at the
University of Missouri, Kansas City. He’s also a
researcher at the Levy Institute at Bard
College. He’s a former Wall Street analyst,
political consultant, and commentator and
author. Michael, thank you so much for taking
the time.
The Destiny of Civilization is based on a
lecture series on finance capitalism and the New
Cold War that Michael Hudson presented for the
Global University for Sustainability.
Luke Parcher: I wanted to
kick things off for the first question. The
title of your book is The Destiny of
Civilization: Finance Capitalism, Industrial
Capitalism, or Socialism.
Can you just explain how you came
to such an all-encompassing title?
[00:01:20] Michael Hudson:
Well, the world economy is now fracturing
between two parts, the United States and Europe
is the dollarized part. And this Western
neoliberal unit is driving Eurasia and most of
the Global South into a separate group. The
conflict really is between finance capitalism in
the United States and Europe against other
countries – China, Russia, Iran, India – that
are following the more traditional ethic and
strategy of industrial capitalism.
The question is: how are
countries going to be economically planned?
Because every economy is planned by somebody. In
the United States, the central planning has been
taken out of the hands of government and put in
Wall Street. In the City of London. A very
rightwing philosophy. In other countries, there
is a mixed economy – China and the rest of
Eurasia – and their objective of planning and
money creation and credit is to create
industrial capital to create the means of
production.
Obviously, also environmental
cleanup now, not merely the means of production
but an overall economic system, not simply to
make fictitious capital, finance capital,
without any reference to the industrial capital
base, the earning of labor and industry
together.
So there are two economic
philosophies and I began the book by contrasting
the dynamics of industrial capitalism with
finance capitalism. And industrial capitalism in
the United States, Germany, England, and every
country where it took off, was to promote a
public investment in basic infrastructure
monopolies in transportation, communication,
education, healthcare.
The idea is that if the
government would provide these basic services
and basic human rights at subsidized rates – or
freely, as in the case of education and
healthcare – then employers would not have to
pay labor a high enough basic wage to make labor
pay for healthcare – as in the United States
where 18% of GDP is for healthcare – or to pay
for education, the 1.7 trillion that goes for
student debt in the United States, not
mentioning the education that is not
debt-financed.
Finance capitalism basically
sought to break away all of the public
infrastructure. Most financial fortunes and
financial fortunes in history were made just in
the way that Zola had described, by prying
thefts from the public domain.
But the financial capitalism
doesn’t say… You don’t have to steal it; you
actually make it your policy, giving away the
financial domain in the way that President
Yeltsin gave away all of Russia’s natural
resources, public utilities, electric companies,
anything that yields an economic rent that can
be just easy income without any investment. And
you financialize it.
You’ve had, for the last – really
since the 1980s, but even since World War 1 –
this movement to prevent industrial economies
from being low cost. But the objective of
finance capitalism, contrary to what’s taught in
the textbooks, is to make economies high cost,
to raise the cost every year.
That actually is the explicit
policy of the Federal Reserve in the United
States. Turn over the central planning to the
banking system to essentially inflate the price
of housing, with government guaranteed
mortgages, up to the point where buying a home
is federally guaranteed up to absorbing 43% of
the borrower’s income.
Well, you take that 43%, you take
the wage withholding for social security and
healthcare, you take the taxes; the domestic
market shrinks and shrinks. And the finance
capital strategy is exactly what it is in the
United States today, in Europe. Shift all of the
money away from the profits of industrial
capital that are reinvested in making new means
of production. To expand capital into a
shrinking economy where the financial sector
intrudes more and more into the economy of
production and consumption and shrinks the
economy.
The rest of the book all spells
out how this transformation from industrial
capitalism to finance capitalism occurred and
how the fight between the United States and
Russia, China, Iraq, Iran, and India – it’s
really a conflict of economic systems. There’s
no rivalry because they’re not trying to do the
same thing. The objectives of the U.S. and
Europe are completely different from the
economic objectives of Eurasia. It’s a war of
economic systems. And that’s why the United
States is trying to prevent other countries from
following the same path to industrial prosperity
that made the United States, Germany and other
countries originally rich.
So you have on the one hand a
high productivity, high standard of living
economy that used to be in the West and is now
in Eurasia, as opposed to an economy of
austerity planned by the IMF and central banks,
as you’re finding in Europe.
Question | Virginia Cotts
[00:06:38] Luke Parcher:
Fantastic. Thank you for that. First here we
have Virginia Cotts, one of the people helping
us backstage, has a question – if Virginia wants
to come on screen and ask.
[00:06:47] Virginia Cotts:
Michael, I’m not an economist. Can you explain
debt deflation – but also how debt siphons money
away from the real economy.
I once heard you say that the
finance sector is the overhead of the real
economy. I think these questions are related? If
you could explain that.
[00:07:09] Michael Hudson:
Well, the classic discussion of debt deflation
was in Volume 3 of Capital, by Marx. And
Marx said that debts tend to grow by compound
interest.
He gave a citation of everybody
from Martin Luther onwards about how any
interest rate is a doubling time, it doubles in
a given number of years. And it grows
exponentially in an up-curve, like X equals Y
squared. But the economy grows in the shape of
an S-curve; it tapers off.
And one of the reasons that it
tapers off in the business cycle is that as the
cycle gains momentum, people go further and
further into debt. And if you have to pay debt
to a banker, if you have to pay student loans,
if you have to pay credit card debt, if you have
to pay mortgages on rising house prices, then
the money you pay to the banker is not available
to be spent on goods and services.
So as you have the debt ratio
growing in every economy, that crowds out the
ability to spend your income on goods and
services. So right now many graduate students –
you graduate from school, you have a student
debt, and you have to live at home with your
parents because you can’t get a mortgage to buy
a house because the banks say, “Well, you’re
already paying so much of your income for
student debt that you don’t have any money left
over to buy a mortgage, so you can’t buy a
mortgage.”
Right now, you’re having the
debt-ridden American economy being squeezed.
More and more money is paid, not only for debt,
but also for other overhead, like healthcare and
various monopoly services that are not available
to buy goods and services.
Debt deflation is when the growth
of debt exceeds the rate of growth of the
economy. And that’s true of every economy. The
most sophisticated mathematical models that I’ve
seen were the ones that were taught to every
student in Babylon in 1750 BC.
We have the models that they were
told. They say, how fast does a debt at the
going rate of interest, at 20%, double? Well,
it’s five years. How long does it take to
redouble? Well, that’s 10 years. How long to
quadruple? Well, that’s 15 years. You see how
fast it is. They also would have students
calculate the growth of a herd of sheep for
instance, and it would all taper off. And when
Assyriologists began to translate these
cuneiform tablets, they thought, well, this must
be an actual report of how the herd actually
grew.
But then they found out that the
Sumerians already in the third millennium had
quadratic equations and very sophisticated
mathematics. The mathematics that they used
5,000 years ago were far in advance of what the
National Bureau of Economic Research uses.
The National Bureau here is
officially in charge of explaining when there’s
a recession, when there’s a boom, and explaining
the business cycle. The basic theory was
outlined and traced by Joseph Schumpeter. It’s a
sign curve going up and down regularly, up and
down. And the whole philosophy of the National
Bureau is a right wing anti-government
philosophy saying the economy has automatic
stabilizers.
It can never get out of balance
because the free market is always going to
prevent any kind of chronic downturn. If you
have a boom, well, prices will rise and that
will cut into profits and that’ll slow
investment. And that’ll means that wages will
fall until it’s more profitable to begin
employing labor again. And you’ll have a
recovery, and things go on and on and on, like a
sign curve, at a given frequency, forever and
ever.
Well, what this deliberately
leaves out of account, deliberately expurgates,
is the fact that every recovery in the United
States and every other Western economy since
1945, has occurred with a rising level of debt.
And as debt grows each time, each recovery has
been slower. And the reason it’s slower is
because as the volume of debt rises, this leaves
less and less income available to spend on goods
and services. And so, the so-called recovery is
weaker until finally it grinds to a halt.
Well, Ricardo anticipated
something like that in 1817 in his Principles
of Political Economy. He said: well, look at
what’s going to happen to land rent. If we don’t
prevent the landlords from being the planners of
the economy, then the more and more population
increases, the price of food will rise, the
rents to the landlords will rise more and more
until the entire economic surplus is paid for
rent and there won’t be any opportunities
available to industrial employers. And Marx
said, well, this was the Armageddon of
capitalism.
In Ricardo’s day, people didn’t
borrow to buy housing. It was still hereditary
landlords. If your ancestors conquered England
and killed enough Englishmen to become
aristocrats, you’d inherit it and you didn’t
have to borrow. But now that real estate has
been democratized in the United States, England
and Europe, you have to go into debt in order to
buy a house.
And the largest amount of debt in
every economy is for real estate, which accounts
for 80% of bank loans in the United States and
England. Essentially, if you want to buy a house
you go to a bank they’ll calculate — well,
here’s the rental value of that house. The
winner, if you’re trying to bid for a house or
an apartment against somebody else, the winner
is the buyer who promises to pay the most for
the property by taking out a bank loan that
absorbs most of the rent as interest. So today,
the rent that Ricardo said was going to drive
industrial capitalism to a halt, is turned into
interest. So it’s the rise in interest that is
the Armageddon of industrial capitalism driving
the economy to a halt.
I chart most of these in my book
Killing the Host, where I give a history
of compound interest. But basically the Western
economies are all subject to debt deflation
today.
And that’s why they’re shrinking.
And living standards here are not rising and the
economy is not growing, in contrast to China,
Russia, Iran, India, and the other countries
that don’t have this kind of financial sector
doing their planning.
Question | Luke Parcher
[00:13:47] Luke Parcher: I
was hoping you could expand on a point you
actually mentioned just before we went live,
distinguishing between different kinds of debt
and which kinds of debt are parasitic and need
to be rid of and which ones do not. Can you just
quickly distinguish between different types of
debt?
[00:14:00] Michael Hudson:
Well, in textbooks that students read,
corporations will borrow from a bank and they
will use this borrowing to build a factory, and
to buy machinery, and to produce something.
And the profits will be paid –
shared 50/50 or so – with the creditor. So a
productive debt is debt which, actually, enables
the creditor to repay the loan with the interest
and still keep something for himself. Banks
don’t lend money to build factories. The stock
market does that. The money the banks lend is
unproductive debt.
Unproductive debt is when the
debt doesn’t enable you to earn more money to
pay the creditor. In an unproductive debt, you
have to earn the money elsewhere and take money
that you may earn as wages or profits and pay
the bank. And it’s your loss. It’s a zero sum
game, not a positive sum game.
Now this distinction between
productive and unproductive debt was built into
Sumerian and Babylonian laws. Only unproductive
debts were canceled under the Jubilee year the
rulers announced. Their word was, andurarum
and, the Hebrew, cognate was deror and
that was the word used for the Jubilee year.
It meant the rural debts – that
when there was a crop failure, and the borrower
could not pay the advance of the land rent and
the other means of production. Obviously, if the
borrower couldn’t repay because there was a crop
failure, or a drought, or a disease, or a flood,
then the debts were wiped out because that debt
did not enable anyone to repay.
And if you didn’t cancel the
debt, then the poor cultivator would be forced
into a debt bondage to the creditor. And if he
did that, then his labor would belong to the
creditor and he couldn’t serve in the army. He
couldn’t go to work on building public
infrastructure. The business debts were all left
in place. Debt denominated in silver were left
in place and not canceled. The debts denominated
in grain were canceled.
Well, in the 12th and 13th
century, crusades flooded Europe with money. The
Christian Church saw that commerce was reviving.
You needed credit. The church theorists said,
okay, there’s a productive debt. You’ll make
loans to a merchant to trade. He’ll have the
money to repay you, that’s productive. But, a
debt to a consumer who can’t, is usury. And so
ancient languages had no words to distinguish
interest from usury.
But the churchmen said, okay,
usury is unproductive debt. Interest is a
productive debt. Those two words, those were the
original meanings of the distinction between
interest and usury. That’s been eradicated today
when everything is considered productive and
part of the free market. And, if it makes the
billionaire class rich, it’s productive. That’s
basically the thing today.
And the only debts that are
supposed to be canceled are debts that the
financial sector owns. The banks don’t have to
pay the billionaires. Only people with less than
a billion dollars have to pay debt. The poorer
you are, the more debt you have to pay. They’ve
reversed the whole last thousand years of
Christian morality as the church has become
privatized and financialized.
Question | L Lewis
[00:17:21] Luke Parcher:
Fantastic. We have a question here in the chat.
This is from L Lewis. It says China has opted
for industrialization and the U.S. corporate
class clearly has not. Why is the U.S. so
belligerent if it doesn’t even want an
industrial system?
[00:17:35] Michael Hudson:
Because it doesn’t want any other country to
have an industrial system. Just like the West
fought against communism threatening a new
social system after the 1917 revolution,
America’s terrified that if China can succeed by
following the exact same policy that the United
States got rich on in the late 19th century,
then they might try to make America rich. And,
oh my God, if they do that then there’s no more
free lunch for the billionaires.
This is life and death for the
billionaires. They make their money by
exploiting the economy without producing. The
Chinese billionaires make their money by
producing and exploiting the economy. But they
also produce a lot. And then they have to give
up much of what they exploit. So the United
States doesn’t want there to be any success in
any country achieving prosperity in a way that
doesn’t siphon off all of the income to the 1%.
Question | Andy Kennedy
[00:18:28] Luke Parcher:
And we have a question here from Andy Kennedy.
[00:18:32] Andy Kennedy:
Michael, I believe that you coined the phrase
monetary hegemony. I believe it was in Super
Imperialism, a book that you wrote a while
back. But I think that’s something that a lot of
people really have a hard time grasping what
that even means. Can you talk a little bit about
how the U.S. dollar hegemony has been a large
part of why the U.S. became de-industrialized.
[00:19:01] Michael Hudson:
Well, that is what my book, Super Imperialism,
was all about, that I published in 1972. Dollar
hegemony really began in 1972. Hegemony is a
word that I can never really work into
conversation very easily. It was actually Henry
Liu that emphasized that term. He’s a friend of
mine and we were colleagues for many years. The
dollar hegemony means the United States can
issue dollar bonds, IOUs, and it never has to
repay them. If we run a balance of payments
deficit in the United States, the dollars end up
in the foreign central banks. Most of the U.S.
balance of payments deficits since the Korean
war have been for military spending.
While America is spending money
on creating military bases all over the world,
these countries will end up with the dollars
that we spend to build the bases and buy off
client oligarchies. And these dollars are turned
over to the local central bank for domestic
currency. And the central bank is going to say,
“What do we do with the dollars?” Well, they
will tend to hold the dollars in the form of
buying a U.S. Treasury bond because central
banks aren’t supposed to take risks.
So they will essentially buy the
Treasury bonds and the United States has no
intention of ever paying the Treasury bonds. How
is it going to pay? It was paying in gold until
1971. So when the United States would spend
money in Vietnam, the dollars that were spent in
Southeast Asia, in Japan, in other countries,
would be sent from Vietnam to their head office
in Paris.
And General de Gaulle would say,
“Well, here are these dollars. Now give us
gold.” And the U.S. gold stock was going down
and down and down. The American strategists
worried that this was going to really hurt the
country’s ability to dominate the world. So when
they went off gold in 1971, everybody thought
that this was going to end American financial
leadership.
Instead, it was a great increase.
It created dollar hegemony because there was
nothing for foreign central banks to hold their
reserves in except U.S. Treasury bills, Treasury
bonds. In other words, Treasury IOUs. So the
more money that America would spend abroad in a
balance of payments deficit, this money would
end up being recycled to the United States in
the form of Treasury securities. And so it was
actually the balance of payments deficit by
military spending that helped finance the U.S.
domestic budget deficit. Other countries really
didn’t have an alternative. And so when the
United States took the lead in creating the
Eurozone, it made sure that the Eurozone would
never make the Euro an alternative currency to
the U.S. dollar because it limited the
Eurozone’s ability to run a budget deficit to
just 3% of GDP.
Well, what that means is that
when Europe goes into a recession and needs to
increase government spending like the United
States does when it’s in a recession, or like
the United States is doing today, running a
budget deficit way in excess of 3% of the GDP,
Europe is not. So there are not enough Euro
bonds by the central bank to ever become a rival
for the United States dollar.
Well, all of this is now being
changed by Russia and China that they have
discussed for the last few years. “In order to
stop U.S. hegemony, we have to avoid financing
our own military encirclement by lending to the
U.S. Treasury that turns it over to the military
industrial complex and Pentagon to build bases
here.So we’re going to have an alternative to
the U.S. dollar.”
Well, they were talking about it
– Russia, China, other countries – really for
five years. And amazingly enough, the end of
dollar hegemony occurred last year when the
United States itself said if any country pursues
a policy that we don’t like, we can grab all of
the dollar reserves that they hold in the United
States.
We can grab all of the Treasury
bonds they hold. We can just take them. All the
bank deposits they have, we can grab. They
grabbed that of Venezuela first. They grabbed
that of Iran. They grabbed that of Afghanistan.
And then they grabbed the $300 billion of
Russia. So now the United States has told any
country, if you do anything that we don’t like,
if you do not let our companies buy control of
your economy, or if you try to sue one of our
oil companies that pollutes your land, we will
grab all of your money and you’ll be isolated.
Well, this ends other countries’
ability to finance the American empire anymore.
Other countries are terrified now. If they’re
all saying “Let’s not denominate our trade in
dollars. Let’s not use the dollars. Let’s use
each other’s currencies. We will finance other
governments’ treasuries.”
And these treasuries that they’re
financing – between China, Russia, Iran, India,
and their neighboring countries – are loans to
help their treasuries build infrastructure and
internal improvements to actually increase the
economy growing. Well, the United States itself
has brought this about by all the sanctions that
it’s imposing. It’s an example of the
self-defeating character of the U.S.
strategists.
Fortunately, none of them
understand how an economy actually works anymore
than they understand how military strategy
really works. So we’re having armchair amateurs
essentially ending a whole system that was
giving America a free lunch for the last 50
years.
[00:24:54] Luke Parcher:
So we have one here in the chat from Jordan
Soreff. He asks, how do you see the interaction
between major shareholders of large financial
institutions and major shareholders of
industrial enterprises? Do you see a lot of
common ownership between these kinds of
institutions? And if so, wouldn’t they
collaborate in order to avoid starving
industrial enterprises of access to credit and
guarantee some basic form of growth, not only
for financial institutions, but also for
industrial enterprises.
[00:25:20] Michael Hudson:
Not at all. They’re collaborating in destroying
the industrial sector. They collaborate in
turning industrial corporations into financial
firms. and when you turn the management of a
corporation away from the engineers and turn it
over to the chief financial officer, the chief
financial officer says, “Our job is not to
increase our industrial production. Our job is
to increase the stock’s price. And we can
maximize the stock’s price by, instead of
spending on research and development that’ll
take years to pay off, we can spend our income
on buying the shares.”
92% of the profits of the Fortune
500 are spent on share buybacks and dividend
payouts, not on new investment. Once you
financialize an industrial corporation, you’re
trying to make money by financial engineering,
not industrial engineering. And you do this by
essentially using your income to buy up the
share price. This is short term – and finance
lives in the short term. The reason finance has
no interest in building up industrial power is
that that takes years and years to actually plan
a factory, plan the production. You have to
develop a whole marketing system.
How are we going to sell the
product once we produce it? How are we going to
distribute it? It takes a lot of planning. It’s
beyond the ability of the financiers. You don’t
need brains to be a financier. All you need is
greed. And you really don’t need a business
school. All you need is greed.
And greed is short term. I want
it now. Greed is not long term planning. And so,
you have a completely different mentality of a
financial corporate leader, as opposed to an
industrial leader. Someone like, let’s say,
Henry Ford, or like the old type of industrial
leaders that would try to increase the overall
profits to expand production more and more.
Today the objective is to shrink production more
and more.
Question | Jonathan Kadmon
[00:27:18] Luke Parcher:
And we have a question here from Jonathan.
[00:27:21] Jonathan Kadmon:
There’s a concept you mentioned in the book
that’s also very near and dear to my heart. The
commodification of essential goods and services,
and extortionist incentives that come when you…
[00:27:32] Michael Hudson:
Is that the title of a book?
[00:27:33] Jonathan Kadmon:
No, it’s definitely a theme you touch on a bunch
of times in your book.
[00:27:37] Michael Hudson:
Oh, okay.
[00:27:37] Jonathan Kadmon:
And I was hoping you could talk a little bit
about how the hostage situation created by
commodifying things like housing, healthcare,
food, transportation, fuel, things like that –
that people need rather than want – is used to
extract rents and siphon wealth out of the
productive economy to service the wealth demand
of the FIRE sector [Finance, Insurance, Real
Estate]
[00:28:00] Michael Hudson:
Well, the free trade ideology that backs
monopolies says that all markets are a function
of choice. But the way to control a market is
not to give the consumers a choice. And when you
say hostage, what that means is people don’t
have a choice between whether to eat or to pay a
bank.
If they have to buy food or if
they have to buy medical care, they have to pay
whatever the going price is. Anatole France said
that the rich person was as free as the poor
person to sleep under the bridge when he didn’t
have a house. So the objective of rent seeking
is to essentially create a situation where
people have no alternative but to buy the
service or the good that you’re producing.
If they have no alternative, then
you can charge whatever you want. This is the
case with most public infrastructure. If you
want to mail a letter, you have to pay whatever
the going postage is, or whatever parcel service
costs. Well, this is why, for about a thousand
years leading up to the late 20th century, all
governments kept basic services in the public
domain – the post office, education, healthcare.
You don’t want to privatize them and leave them
to the market because if you leave them to the
market, then it really isn’t a matter of choice
at all.
It’s a matter of letting a
monopolist take something that everybody needs,
no matter what the price, and charge as much as
the market will bear. And that’s a rent-seeking
monopoly. That basically is the philosophy that
Margaret Thatcher, Ronald Reagan, and the free
marketers developed since the 1980s, when you
had a privatization of basic needs, especially
in housing. And the most important utility
that’s been privatized of course has been money
and credit creation – the banking system. What
has enabled China to avoid the financialization
that’s occurred in the United States is because
the Central Bank of China is run by the
government, not by a financial oligarchy of
bankers that get together to run the credit
system for their own benefit. But if the
government treats money as a public utility,
everybody needs money, everybody needs credit,
and the government will provide the credit as
needed for the economy to grow.
And if the economy has a
slowdown, or if a company runs into a financial
problem, if you’re the government as a creditor,
you can write down the debt. In the United
States, if you’ve made loans to a company like
General Electric and all of a sudden it can’t
pay, the company either goes bankrupt or begins
to sell off its assets piece by piece to other
people and you have industry being turned into
gentrified luxury housing.
So the same thing with
healthcare. If you privatize healthcare,
everybody needs to go to the hospital. Everybody
needs doctor care. If you privatize it then in
the United States, 18% of your GDP is going to
go to healthcare. The objective is to make
healthcare as inefficient and cheap as possible
to maximize the profits of the health insurance
companies. And the sicker you get, the more
money they make.
Also, by the way, the sicker you
get, the more GDP goes up. GDP goes up because
you have to spend more money healing yourself.
So, that’s, a growing part of the American GDP –
along with rent and debt service and interest.
Well, if you keep healthcare in the public
sector, the public sector is going to try to
actually keep people healthy instead of sick.
And they’re trying to minimize the expense of
getting sick so that you leave more money in the
hands of households to spend on the real economy
of production and consumption, not on giving
money to the monopolies.
But in the United States the main
utility beside money that’s been privatized is
government. Under the Citizens United ruling,
the government is now really up for sale and
auctioned off to the highest campaign
contributors. In the Democratic Party, for
instance, every Democratic representative has to
raise a given amount of money from campaign
contributors to give to the Democrat National
Committee.
So whoever can raise the most
money gets to be the committee heads. Well,
you’ll have the pharmaceuticals industry giving
a lot of money to some representative they want
to be head of the health committee. You’ll have
the bankers giving money to whoever they want to
be the head of the banking committee and so on.
So, the function of government itself once it’s
privatized is to make money for the donor class,
which basically is the financial class and the
monopoly class that finance creates. Banks have
always been the mother of monopolies and the
financial sector’s largest business market is in
creating monopolies. So, you have basically the
privatization of monopolies.
And the monopoly rent of these
monopolies is used for paying interest to the
banks that finance the corporate raiders, or
whoever wants to take over and buy these
monopoly privileges.
Question | Luke Parcher
[00:33:14] Luke Parcher:
We have a question here from Paul Birtwell.
Paul, go ahead.
[00:33:18] Paul B: Hi, Dr.
Hudson. Could you briefly touch on the concept
of economic rent and unearned income as well as
how the establishment became established by
conquering Europe, privatizing the commons all
the way up through colonialism, and how they use
all these little privileges through copyrights,
patents, formula, and it’s not really through
effort or innovation, but it’s through rake off.
I remember you in an interview,
I’m paraphrasing, saying something like: For the
crime of being conquered, the 99% and all of the
descendants are obligated to take care of the 1%
and all of their descendants into perpetuity.
But it would be great if you
could touch on those historical elements because
most folks think, “Hey, these folks that are
really rich are smarter, they worked harder.”
And as we know, it’s not based on effort or
individual contribution but rather just milking
society.
[00:34:16] Michael Hudson:
Well, it’s very hard to answer that question
very briefly in a question and answer. I’ve
written two chapters of the Destiny of
Civilization describing exactly what you’ve
asked: economic rent. All classical economics –
from Adam Smith through Ricardo, John Stuart
Mill, Marx, Alfred Marshall – was all about
value and price theory in order to segregate how
much of the price is not reflected by a real
cost of production. Economic rent is unnecessary
income.
Economic rent is what you’re
able to charge more than just the cost of
producing goods and service with a profit. It’s
“What is a free lunch?” And the free marketers
say, “There’s no such thing as a free lunch.”
That’s what Milton Friedman said. But a rentier
economy is all about a free lunch. The concept
of economic rent in the 19th century was aimed
at landlords because they inherited the land.
The land does not have a cost of production. And
yet, if you have an ownership right to the land,
a privilege of legal ownership of the land, you
have a legal boundary and you can charge rent
without any effort of your own.
John Stuart Mill said economic
rent is what landlords make in their sleep. They
don’t have to make a productive effort. Well,
actually a theory of rent went way back to the
churchmen in the 13th century describing what is
a fair return to bankers. The economy needs
credit, all economies work on credit, traders
need credit. They need the money exchange from
one currency to another. The value of banking
services is the cost of living, the cost of
doing business, the cost to have a certain
lifestyle that’s becoming of a banker.
But everything that’s over and
above normal living prosperity and costs is
called usury. That’s not a valid cost. And so
that was deemed illegal already in the 13th
century. Well, Ricardo in the 19th century used
the landlords as the main rent recipients of the
hereditary landed aristocracy. Rent is what a
landlord would get just for the ownership
privilege of having a land. And so if you go out
and buy a house today and the price of land goes
up because the city will increase bus service or
a transportation service. For instance, in New
York City, a few years ago, they extended and
built the Second Avenue subway that went uptown,
along Second Avenue. Real estate prices all
soared for real estate on Second Avenue. That
was a free lunch.
The landlords didn’t do anything
at all to increase the real estate rents that
they were charging. Rents went way up. If you
lived on Second Avenue or First Avenue, even
Third Avenue, you had to pay much higher rent
because you no longer had to walk half a mile to
get to the Lexington subway that was very
overcrowded. You could have the nice uncrowded,
Second Avenue subway.
And yet, this rent increased not
by the expenditure of any cost. It was rent
without value. It was the price of housing
without cost value. So rent is the unnecessary
element of price over and above what it actually
costs to produce something. And rentier income
is the income that is unnecessary.
To actually pay a industrialist
for building a factory… industrialists would be
happy with making the normal rate of profit. But
if you have a special technology monopoly like
the drug companies, then you can make
super-profits. So rents are super-profits,
basically. That’s the difference. Anyway, that’s
to your question.
Question | Roxanne D
[00:37:58] Luke Parcher:
Right on. We have, a question here from Roxanne
Devereaux. She says, if you’ve answered this,
maybe just elaborate on your answer, but in a
perfect world where government actually served
the people, what would a debt jubilee look like
and how could it reverberate through society?
Most examples I’m familiar with
happened before the industrial revolution.
[00:38:14] Michael Hudson:
Well, the best example is the German financial
miracle of 1947, 1948, the allied monetary
reform. All internal debts were canceled except
for people’s bank accounts up to a given amount
and except for the money that employers owed
their employees.
And the reason is that most of
the wealth, most of the bank deposits, most of
the creditors’ claims, were by the Nazis. And
the American occupation said, well, we don’t
want the Nazis to get rich. So the good thing
about canceling debts is you cancel the savings
of bad guys. In 1947 it was the Nazis; today
it’s the 1%.
If you cancel the debts that
I’ve said should be canceled – the sort of bad
debts that are not necessarily production – then
you cancel all of this vast accumulation of
savings by the 1%. For instance, if you cancel
student debts, that would free income for
spending on democracy.
If you cancel all the debts that
US banks owe to the offshore banking centers in
the Caribbean, Panama, Liberia. All of this is
flight capital. This is criminal capital. Cancel
out all the debt of criminal capital and fraud.
When Greece was running into its financial
crisis seven years ago, Greece owed 50 billion
euros of debt that it was trying to write down.
And the IMF produced a list
called the Lagarde List that had deposits of
Greek crooks and tax evaders in Switzerland were
$50 billion. That 50 billion could have been
wiped out. One of the first debt cancellations
that went wrong was in Sparta in the third
century, BC, under Agis and Cleomenes. When they
canceled the debts, the people who wanted to
cancel the debts were people who’d bought land
on credit and they wanted their debt.
They wanted to own the land free
and clear and cancel the mortgages. So some
debts you don’t want to write down. If you were
to write down mortgage debts, Donald Trump and
real estate speculators would be the richest
people in the country. So you don’t want to
write down their debts.
Their debts will remain on the
books. But if they were written down, well,
first of all then, their debts are the banking
systems assets. So Citibank would be even more
insolvent than it is already and the banks would
go under. They would be taken over by the public
sector because if you have the mortgage debt
wiped out, there’s still economic rent. Because
people are willing to pay more money for a
well-situated property that would, uh, in place
of the banks getting the rental value as
mortgage debt, the government would get the same
rental value in the form of a land tax. That was
what classical economics was all about. That was
Adam Smith. That was John Stuart Mill. That was
the whole reform movement of the late 19th
century. So you want to cancel the bad debts,
but you don’t want to make debtors who are just
speculators rich in the process.
You want to make sure that you
only cancel the bad debts and you don’t create a
new rentier class. The idea is to look at the
economy as a system and see what should the
government receive as economic rent. And it can
decide what is it going to receive for
healthcare. The government… if the government
took over the healthcare industry, it probably
would not charge the prices that healthcare
charges today. It would charge less. Same thing
for housing. If housing were run like England
ran its council housing before Margaret
Thatcher, it would be very low. In Germany,
Germany pays only 10% of its average family
income for rent, not 30 or 40% as in the case of
the United States.
That’s what used to make
Germany, until last month, so competitive an
economy. So, you’d restructure the economy so
that it would only have debts that were socially
necessary to keep the economy operating. Debts
will begin to grow all over again.
Debts will always begin to grow
over and over again. If you don’t ban interest,
you permit debts to grow, but when they get so
problematic that they threaten economic growth,
then you have to write them down to a level
where they will no longer prevent economic
growth from occurring as they’re doing today.
Question | Doug G
[00:42:45] Luke Parcher:
So we have one from Doug Greer here. He says
many people seem to confuse the lessons of MMT
with the super imperialism of the US dollar
being the reserve currency of the world. Is the
ability to create dollars to finance domestic
needs of the US, like healthcare and
infrastructure, dependent on the US dollar being
the reserve currency?
Can you clarify?
[00:43:05] Michael Hudson:
They’re completely separate. Any country can use
its credit creation, either by the central bank
or by commercial banks, to create credit. It
doesn’t have to be linked to the balance of
payments, except that if a country’s running a
balance of payments deficit its currency will
fall, unless it can balance the payments
somehow.
So they are different questions.
Question | Fabiano D
[00:43:30] Luke Parcher:
We have one from Fabiano D. Being that
politicians, therefore government, are in the
pockets of the rentier class, how do you think
we could get rid of such rentier influence in
order to implement socially oriented policies?
[00:43:43] Michael Hudson:
That has never happened without a revolution.
That’s the problem. How do you get rid of them?
Well, I don’t see any way for the United States
to get rid of them. It took a revolution in
China. It took a revolution in Russia. That’s
the problem right there.
You did have the beginning of a
peaceful revolution in England in the 19th
century and, leading to a constitutional crisis
in 1909 and 1910, when the House of Commons
actually passed the land tax and the House of
Lords, being the landed aristocracy, canceled
it. That caused a crisis.
And the upshot was the House of
Lords was never, again, going to be able to
negate a revenue act passed by the House of
Commons. So that was actually a peaceful
resolution of a constitutional crisis. Then
World War I came and changed everything. But
today I don’t see that kind of a peaceful
resolution occurring in the United States.
They’re not going to repeal the
Citizens United act, and, from what it looks
like to me, the economy is going to get more and
more highly squeezed and more polarized between
the 1% and the 99%. I would say it’s a class war
except finance isn’t really a class because
everybody is a creditor as well as a debtor in
some sense or another. So it’s really a
financial dynamic against the rest of the
economy. One of the points that Marx made in
Volume 3 of Capital was that finance
grows by purely mathematical laws of its own,
having no relation to the growth of the economy.
It’s an autonomous economic system.
And I think that autonomous
economic system is independent of the government
here and yet, unless you have a study of
economics as an economic system – understanding
what’s causing the polarization and the poverty
in the United States – you’re not going to be
able to have a reform movement to change the
system.
The role of economics
departments is to dumb down the understanding of
the economy. You’re not going to have any kind
of a peaceful reform movement here.
Question | Cristina
[00:45:47] Luke Parcher:
We have a question here from Cristina who asks,
what are the steps we can take to fix the
housing crisis? Kind of a broad question, but if
you have any policy prescriptions there, that
would be great.
[00:45:57] Michael Hudson:
There’s very little that individuals can do. The
19th century dealt with this question
increasingly. And their solution was if you have
a calculation of the land rent, as opposed to
what it costs to build a building – we all know
that if you build a building the contractor and
the builder or developer have to make a profit,
but if the government will tax the land rent,
then it will not be available to the banks to
charge as interest.
So, if you tax the land rent,
then the land rent is not going to be
capitalized into a bank loan, and housing prices
will be kept down to the actual cost of
construction plus normal profits. And as housing
becomes more desirable, or as the economy
becomes more profitable, or as cities build more
Second Avenue subways and the rental value goes
up, the taxes will go up. That will prevent this
increased rent from taking a financial form and
will simply be the source of a government
revenue. It requires a tax system to tax away
the economic rent, so that housing does not
reflect the speculation and the economic rent
that is caused by the privatization that’s been
occurring. Especially since 2008.
Question | Tim
[00:47:11] Luke Parcher:
So this one is from Tim. Tim says one argument
against de-dollarization is the liquidity and
stability of the US dollar. For example, oil is
based in dollars and many OPEC countries have
their currencies pegged to the dollar, such that
they benefit from a strong dollar. At this age,
the transition into trade in local currency
pairs against these advantages of dollar as
reserve currency.
[00:47:32] Michael Hudson:
Well, that’s exactly what this last weekend’s
Shanghai cooperation meetings were all about.
Any country that holds its central bank reserves
in dollars has a stake and in wanting to lose
the money. China has the largest dollar holdings
of any government and its currency has gone down
and down and down.
China’s willing to take a loss
on this by moving out of the dollars. The
solution is, as both President Xi and President
Putin pointed out, we’re going to move out of
the dollar so we don’t have a stake in the
dollar. It can go up or down. It is not going to
bother us. They’re not buying or selling to us
anymore.
Anyway, they’re sanctioning us.
So let’s go with what president Biden wants. He
says, you go your way, we’ll go our way. Fine.
Let’s go our own ways and use each other’s
currency, and that way, it won’t matter. So, it
won’t matter to them. If moving out of the
dollar means that there’s less demand for the
dollars and it goes down, what they’re gaining
is freedom.
So, this is the price of their
economic liberty from dollar diplomacy.
[00:48:34] Luke Parcher:
We have another question here from Virginia
Cotts.
Question | Virginia Cotts
[00:48:36] Virginia Cotts:
Michael, I feel like we have… some people have a
lot of nostalgia for the post World War II
social democracies of Europe. I can’t remember
if it was in your book or in an interview you
described Thatcher’s process of privatizing in
England. Could you talk about that? Because I
didn’t know a lot of that.
[00:49:00] Michael Hudson:
Well, Margaret Thatcher said that her greatest
contribution was Tony Blair. And Tony Blair was
an opportunist who got enough support from the
United States to move the British Labour party
to the right of the Conservative Party and do
what Margaret Thatcher never could have done. By
even privatizing the railroads, by being more
viciously anti-labor, the social democratic
parties in every country have been so pushed by
what the CIA called “the mighty Wurlitzer of
public opinion” – meaning bribes to the
politicians – that they’ve financed the
campaigns of neoliberals to pretend to be
pro-labor, to pretend to be socialist, while
actually they’re the far right wing of the
political spectrum. I won’t call them fascist.
But let’s just say there’s nothing the fascists
would not like in the social democratic parties.
So, here you have the most right wing parties in
Europe are the social democratic parties. Way to
the right.
I guess the most right wing
neofascist party is, of course, the Greens in
Germany that are the pro-war party. And
anti-labor. But basically, there is no longer a
real labor party representing the interests of
labor. They’ve all been co-opted by demagogues.
The social democratic parties in a way have been
like the peace parties.
The first thing that every peace
party does when there’s a war is they’re at the
head of the pro-war patriotism parade. That was
what Trotsky noted about World War One. The
peace parties jumped on the bandwagon in
Germany, Austria, England, America. Social
democratic parties have done the same thing when
there’s a neoliberal right wing corporatist
financialization. They’ve all been persuaded to
do it.
The equivalent was like what the
Clintons did to the United States since the
1990s. In the United States, the Democratic
Party is the far right wing party now. And I
guess when I answered the question about what
can Americans do to help the housing crisis… You
cannot solve the housing crisis until you end
the Democratic Party. You cannot solve the labor
problem without ending the Democratic Party.
Because that is the party of Wall Street. That
is the party of the 1%. Its function is to make
sure that there cannot be any left wing
opposition to block the Republican Party’s
program.
What Bill Clinton did, the
Republicans never could have done. Backing Alan
Greenspan and the right wingers in getting rid
of the acts preventing banks from owning
insurance companies and brokerage houses.
Getting rid of the Glass Steagall Act. And no
Republican could have done anything as viciously
anti-black and anti-Hispanic as President Obama,
whose policies are basically identical with
those of the Ku Klux Klan.
Obama’s role was essentially to
reverse the attempt by blacks and hispanics to
become homeowners. His objective was to replace
black home ownership and hispanic home ownership
with ownership by private capital companies. His
role in 2009 was to bail out the banks – the
fraudulent banks that had written the junk
mortgages – and to keep the junk mortgages on
the hook to evict almost 10 million American
families. And not fine the banks, not throw a
single crooked banker in jail. This ended the
hopes of the low income Americans – and
especially the minorities – to have housing.
If you say, what can we do about
housing? Well, if you’re black or Hispanic, you
must avoid the Democratic Party like the plague.
And you must come to terms with the fact that it
was Obama that was the most anti-black president
of the 20th century, except of course for
Woodrow Wilson. The damage that he’s done has
not been widely recognized here.
And, he has put in place a
Democratic Party leadership that is so
anti-labor, so white racist. and so pro-Wall
Street that I don’t think it is reformable.
Question | Luke Parcher
[00:53:18] Luke Parcher:
And just to build on what you were just talking
about there, Michael, I’m kind of stunned by the
extent to which people buy into the partisan
false dichotomy in this country and seem to
think there are all these massive differences
between the parties.
And that obviously is an
issue-by-issue thing, but I’m curious where you
think that buy-in comes from and how we might be
able to cut into it. The fear mongering about
Trump is I think overstating the differences
between Trump and Biden on these issues. Can you
talk a little bit about that?
[00:53:43] Michael Hudson:
Yes. The Republican Party’s role is to say to
Wall Street, “Yes, please.” And the Democratic
Party’s policy is to say “Yes, thank you.” But
that’s basically it. You’ll notice, like in
Ohio, the Democratic National Committee is
backing a right-winger who is going to play the
role of West Virginia Senator Manchin or
Arizona’s Sinema. The Democrats want to make
sure that it has enough Republicans running as
Democrats, that if there’s ever a danger of
promoting a bill that is good for the working
class or the racial minorities or ethnic
minorities, that you’ll have the Republicans
running as Democrat to cancel it, to play the
role.
There’ll always be many senators
right behind Manchin and Sinema in the wings to
prevent the Democrats from doing anything that
does not serve the short-term immediate
interests of their Wall Street bankers… Backers.
Question | Bruce W
[00:54:39] Luke Parcher:
Rotating villain is a very real concept for
sure. We have a question here from Bruce Wall
who asks, which of the public banking and
monetary reform movements do you support, if
any? I have in mind Public Banking Institute,
American Monetary Institute, the Alliance of
Just Money, Christine Desan’s Just Money. What
about figures like Robert Hockett?
[00:54:58] Michael Hudson:
Well, I’m on the board of directors of the
Public Banking Institute. Steve Zarlenga was a
good friend of mine.
I was at all of his early
conferences. So they both have very good ideas.
And… I’m blocking out the name. Who’s the head
of the public banking?
[00:55:15] Virginia Cotts:
That’s not Ellen Brown, is it?
[00:55:17] Michael Hudson:
Yeah. Ellen Brown. Ellen would be all in favor
of many of the things I’ve talked about, but she
doesn’t think that a debt cancellation is
politically feasible right now. And of course,
she’s right. So she’s said that, well, public
banks can provide the model for what could be.
The result of what happens if Obama would have
let Citibank go bankrupt.
The Republican head of the FDIC
[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation] urged
that Citibank, being run by crooks… but, Obama
put an even bigger crook in charge. Geithner,
who was working for his banker Robert Rubin,
basically did not let Citibank go bankrupt
because that would’ve wiped out the
stockholders.
And as Sheila Bair, the head of
FDIC, said, well, it was all about the bond
holders. And Sheila said, if Citigroup would’ve
gone under, then that meant the government
would’ve had the biggest bank in the country,
and it could actually run a commercial bank
along making good loans instead of making loans
to corporate raiders. Instead of making crooked
mortgage loans and fake loans, it could actually
make loans to help the economy grow. Well, she’s
quite right. That would’ve been a good idea.
So she’s concentrated.on public
banks for what they can do. And she said, at
least by having a public bank, you’ll keep the
deposits of the public sector – the government,
the state agencies, and hopefully the local city
agencies – in the public domain, out of the
hands of, the commercial bankers and Wall
Street, so that you can use the money for a good
purpose.
So, I’m all in favor of what
she’s doing. Steve Zarlenga at American monetary
Institute was for the hundred percent reserve
plan that was proposed in the 1930s. And that
is, commercial banks would actually be reduced
to the status of savings banks.
A hundred percent reserves.
Could not create credit. They could only make
loans from deposits. Of course, if they had a
productive loan made, the government, the
Treasury, would act as the depositor – simply
increase the deposits in the bank to enable them
to make productive loans.
And that also, in principle, is
a very good idea. That’s why I supported that.
And of course that was the program that was
introduced by Dennis Kusinich in his
presidential run. I was Kusinich’s economic
advisor. So those are the two groups that I’m
most familiar with and the most in favor of.
Question | Rasha
[00:57:41] Luke Parcher:
We have a question here from Rasha. What role
does defining money play in shaping the economy?
How do you define money? Is it a record of value
transferred between economic actors or is it a
commodity? If you agree that money is a record
of value transferred between two or more
economic actors, isn’t it possible to create
money on demand by any two or more economic
actors in a decentralized manner, as opposed to
central private banks providing there is a
scientific formula by which value of goods and
services is assigned.
[00:58:10] Michael Hudson:
Oh, my God. I can’t even begin to answer that.
The jargon is so misleading. Money has nothing
to do with value. Money is debt. That’s the
opposite of value. It’s a transfer of debt among
people, it’s not a transfer of value. You’re
using a very right wing, quite frankly, a
fascist economic terminology, maybe without
meaning to. But it’s not value, it’s debt
created out of thin air. It’s credit.
When you go into a bank and you
take out a loan the bank doesn’t say let me see
how much money I have on deposit to lend you.
They will just write you a loan. They’ll create
a bank deposit and in exchange you’ll give them
an IOU. It’s debt, loans, that create deposits,
not the other way around. Anyone who talks about
money and value, you want to stop talking to
them immediately. Because you know that it’s
just going to be patter talk for propaganda.
Question | Tom
[00:59:03] Luke Parcher:
So we have one here from Tom. Tom asks: all
prices of all things for sale are not rising.
Therefore, the term inflation is not what we are
experiencing. For example, the market is
working. Money is moving from those without oil
to those with oil.
Why does no trained economist
understand and label this a normal market
redistribution period or some term listed in
textbooks for reference? And why is the concept
called inflation, which scares unknowing
economists and today’s consumers who needlessly
suffer from money famine, so poorly taught and
so poorly understood?
[00:59:33] Michael Hudson:
The question is so bizarre, I cannot answer it.
It’s just how do you, how do you answer a swamp
and straighten out what they’re saying to give
them an answer? It’s a swamp. I can’t answer
that.
[00:59:42] Luke Parcher:
I suppose in general, what would you prescribe
the price increases that we’ve seen today to?
[00:59:47] Michael Hudson:
Very largely monopoly positions. The reason oil
prices are going up is not because there’s an
oil shortage. It’s because the oil companies
find an excuse to use the newspaper reports that
there will be an oil shortage at some
point to raise the prices right now. Adam Tooze
wrote a good article a few days ago, comparing
the inflation in Europe to the inflation in the
United States. In Europe, the price inflation is
almost exclusively for energy and for oil and
gas derivatives. In the United States, the
inflation is much broader – it’s over the whole
course.
Again, you want to look at the
economy as a system. You don’t want to reduce
everything to one-dimensional “here’s the price
level”. You want to look at the multi-layered
economy. What are the cost prices? What are the
economic rents? What are the monopoly prices?
What’s the tax system? You have to look at the
economy as a system, not in a one-dimensional
way. So, I can’t untangle all of the jumble any
clearer than that.
Question | Paul B
[01:00:55] Luke Parcher:
We have one here from Paul Birtwell again. Could
Dr. Hudson touch on and acknowledge the validity
of MMT? What do you think is the importance of
MMT and how does it apply to this discussion?
[01:01:04] Michael Hudson:
Well, I was on the faculty of the UMKC, which is
MMT center for many years. I’m all in favor of
MMT. The point of MMT is that just as banks
create endogenous credit on their own computers,
the government can create credit. The government
doesn’t have to borrow money from the 1% or from
bond holders in order to spend it; the
government can simply print it as it did under
the greenbacks.
The government can create its
own credit. And there’s nothing wrong with
running a budget deficit because a budget
deficit does not have to be paid by taxpayers
paying taxes. A government deficit can be funded
by simply creating the money on your own
computer – not by taxes. That’s the point that
Stephanie Kelton has been making again and again
in what she writes.
And that really is the essence
of MMT. But of course the leading exponent of
MMT was Donald.Trump, when he said deficits
don’t matter, we can just create whatever we
want. And I think, Vice President Cheney also
said we can spend whatever we want. It doesn’t
matter. George Bush said, you know, it’s all
really fictitious anyway; we can do it.
The difference between Donald
Trump and the Republicans and the MMTers is, we
want the government to run deficits to actually
spend into the economy. We do not want deficits
to be run for $9 trillion to subsidize
quantitative easing for the 1% to promote real
estate prices and stock and bond prices.
We want them to actually employ
workers and to promote full employment. So the
difference is that the MMTers are basically in
favor of tangible economic growth, not creating
money bad MMT of Cheney and Donald Trump style.
Question | Luke Parcher
[01:02:51] Luke Parcher:
Can you talk a little bit about how the IMF
[International Monetary Fund] and
financialization have contributed to what’s
going on right now in Ukraine? I know that’s a
little bit broad, but if you could tie in what
we’ve been talking about here to the situation
in Ukraine.
[01:03:02] Michael Hudson:
The IMF’s job is to make sure that the economy
is impoverished and that all the money that it
gives is to support the currency – to enable the
kleptocrats, Kolomoyskyi and others, to take the
Ukrainian currency they have and transfer it
into dollars and pound sterling at a high
exchange rate.
So they will lend Ukraine the
dollars – essentially to support the hryvnia,
however you pronounce its currency – and enable
the kleptocrats to make money and then pull the
rug out from under them if any alternatives to
the Nazis take power. They want.to make sure
that, once the kleptocrats have emptied out the
economy, they can let the economy collapse.
They’re of course backing the
new labor law president Zelensky has pushed,
abolishing labor unions, abolishing the rights
of labor to negotiate, and making basically the
most fascist labor law in any country’s history.
So the role of the IMF is to support client
oligarchy, to get their money out of a country
before there is a possibility of a leftwing
government coming in, and then to deny all
credit and organize a currency raid on the
leftwing government, to say, “You see, socialism
doesn’t work”.
The IMF is one of the
institutions that is the arm of American
hegemony, preventing economic growth occurring
outside of the United States. Essentially the
IMF is a… it’s a small office in the basement of
the Pentagon, run by the neocons, to make sure
that other countries cannot have any policy that
would not let American firms come in and buy
their raw materials and their natural resources
and their monopolies.
So, think of the IMF as a tool
of the military, but much more right wing than
any general would dare to be.
[01:04:55] Luke Parcher:
Thank you so much, Michael. We really appreciate
you taking the time today.
I also, once again, want to
remind people to please go to
realprogressives.org to learn more about us, or
find our podcasts and articles, including again,
Michael, as a guest on Macro N Cheese. With
that, we will go ahead and call it a discussion
here. Virginia, did you have anything you wanted
to add?
[01:05:12] Virginia Cotts:
Yes. I wanted to ask Michael where people can
find his work.
[01:05:17] Michael Hudson:
Well, Amazon, I guess, is the easiest place to
go. It’s all available there.
On my website,
michael-hudson.com. And you can go to that and
join me on Patreon. I do have a Patreon group,
and if you’re a contributor at a given level,
then you get to talk to me directly every few
months.
[01:05:36] Virginia Cotts:
Well, we can all use support. Real Progressives
also has a Patreon. So, support us all, please.
I just want to say, Michael, you
wrote an article with the greatest title I’ve
ever seen, which was something like the US
Defeats Germany for the Third Time in a Century.
I just thought that was such a perfect title. I
think you wrote it right when the Ukraine war
was beginning.
[01:06:02] Michael Hudson:
Right. It was apparent what was going to happen
at the very beginning. And I’m amazed that
nobody else was writing about that. I’m not very
good on military analysis. I can follow what
Andrei Raevsky at the Saker says, and Moon of
Alabama, and Andrei Martyanov. The one thing I
can tell about military operations is the
balance of payments aspects and how it all is
spelled out.
[01:06:24] Virginia Cotts:
Well… and you talked about how the three main
sectors benefited.
[01:06:30] Michael Hudson:
Yes. Oil is the key to American diplomacy. And I
guess if we’re talking about American hegemony,
it comes from America’s control of the oil
trade. That was one of the reasons that America
wanted to isolate first Venezuela, and then
Russia, because if the only source of oil are
companies controlled by the American oil majors,
then…
Every economy needs energy to
grow. And in every economy since the beginning
of the industrial revolution, there’s a
connection between the growth of GDP and energy
use per capita. So I talk about the monopoly
rent and the victim economy. If you can control
oil then you can control, basically, the world
economy.
That has been a key to the
American policy. The Americans realized that if
Europe cannot buy Russian oil anymore, or
Venezuelan oil, then it’ll have to spend 10
times as much buying American liquified natural
gas. This means the sanctions against Russia
have ended German industrial supremacy. It has
ended the German steel industry. It has ended
German heavy industry.
They’re now going to be
dependent thoroughly on the United States. And
the euro is going to become a weakening
satellite currency of the US dollar as a result
of killing off the German economic and
industrial leadership of the European economy,
along with that of Italy and France.
[01:07:53] Virginia Cotts:
Oh, thank you. I hope we didn’t abuse your
generosity with your time.
[01:07:59] Michael Hudson:
No. I assume if I said anything controversial,
you’ll just take it out.
[01:08:03] Virginia Cotts:
Oh, no, we like it. We will actually clip it and
plaster it all over the internet.
[01:08:12] Luke Parcher:
Oh… [laughs]
[01:08:13] Virginia Cotts:
Michael Hudson isn’t controversial, is he?
[01:08:18] Luke Parcher:
Well, you certainly don’t mince words, and we
very much appreciate that about you. Michael,
thanks again for giving us so much time today.
And I want to give a brief shout out to Jonathan
Kadmon, Andy Kennedy, and Virginia Cotts, who’ve
been helping behind the scenes today to make
this happen.
Thanks to all involved. Great.
[01:08:31] Michael Hudson:
Thanks for having me. I liked the discussion.
Luke Parcher: - For those
who might not know me, I’m Luke Parcher, I’m a
student and activist. I volunteer with Real
Progressives. I’m on our leadership team and I
also do a show on Sundays covering politics and
current events, and I do some interviews
throughout the week and things which you guys
can find on Real Progress in Action.
I want to quickly talk about Real
Progressives. If you’re interested in learning
more about us, you can go to
www.realprogressives.org . We have articles,
content, podcasts, all sorts of things.
Views expressed in this article are
solely those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect the opinions of Information Clearing House. in this article are
solely those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect the opinions of Information Clearing House.
Reader financed- No
Advertising - No Government Grants -
No Algorithm - This
Is Independent
In accordance
with Title 17 U.S.C. Section 107, this material
is distributed without profit to those who have
expressed a prior interest in receiving the
included information for research and educational
purposes. Information Clearing House has no
affiliation whatsoever with the originator of
this article nor is Information ClearingHouse
endorsed or sponsored by the originator.)