By Richard D. Wolff
May 02, 2021 "Information
Clearing House" - Throughout its
history—wherever it arrived and settled in
as the dominant economic system—capitalism
provoked struggles over the redistribution
of wealth. In other words, this system
always distributes wealth in a particular
way and likewise produces dissatisfaction
with that particular distribution. Those
dissatisfied then struggle, more or less,
consciously or not, peacefully or violently
to redistribute wealth. The struggles are
socially divisive and sometimes rise to
civil war levels.
The French Revolution marked the end of
French feudalism and its transition to
capitalism. The revolutionaries’ slogans
promised the transition would bring with it
“liberté, égalité, fraternité” (liberty,
equality and fraternity). In other words,
equality was to be a key accompaniment to or
product of capitalism’s establishment, of
finally replacing feudalism’s lord-serf
organization of production with capitalism’s
very different employer-employee system.
Transition to capitalism would erase the
gross inequalities of French feudalism. The
American Revolution likewise broke not only
from its British colonial master but also
from the feudal monarchy of George III. “All
men are created equal” was a central theme
of its profound commitment to equality
together with capitalism.
In France, the United States and beyond,
capitalism justified itself by reference to
its achievement or at least its targeting of
equality in general. This equality included
the distribution of wealth and income, at
least in theory and rhetoric. Yet from the
beginning, all capitalisms wrestled with
contradictions between lip service to
equality and inequality in their actual
practices. Adam Smith worried about the
“accumulation of stock” (wealth or
“capital”) in some hands but not in others.
Thomas Jefferson and Alexander Hamilton had
different visions of the future of an
independent United States in terms of
whether it would or would not secure wealth
equality later dubbed “Jeffersonian
democracy.” There was and always remained in
the United States an awkward dissonance
between theoretical and rhetorical
commitments to equality and the realities of
slavery and then systemic racist
inequalities. The inequalities of gender
likewise contradicted commitments to
equality. It took centuries of capitalism to
achieve even the merely formal political
equality of universal suffrage.
No Advertising - No Government Grants - This Is
Independent Media
Thus, there should be no surprise that
U.S. capitalism—like most other
capitalisms—provokes a widely troubling
contradiction between the actual wealth
inequality it produces and tendentially
deepens (as Thomas Piketty has definitively
shown) and its repeatedly professed
commitment to equality. Efforts to
redistribute wealth—to thereby move from
less to more equal distributions—follow.
Yet, they also disturbingly divide societies
where the capitalist economic system
prevails.
Wealth redistributions take from those
who have and give to those who have not.
Those whose wealth is redistributed resent
or resist this taking, while those who
receive during the redistributions of wealth
develop rationales to justify that receipt.
Each side of such redistributions often
demonizes the other. Politics typically
becomes the arena where demonizations and
conflicts over redistribution occur. Those
at risk of being deprived due to
redistributions aim either to oppose
redistribution or else to escape it. If the
opposition is impossible or difficult,
escape is the chosen strategy. Thus, if
profits of capitalists are to be taxed to
redistribute wealth to the poor, big
businesses may escape by moving politically
to shift the burden of taxation onto small
or medium businesses. Alternatively, all
businesses may unite to shift the burden of
such redistributive taxation onto
higher-paid employees’ wages and salaries,
and away from business profits.
Recipients of redistributions face
parallel political problems of whom to
target for contributing to wealth
redistribution. Will recipients support a
tax on all profits or rather a tax just on
big business with maybe some redistribution
flowing from big to medium and small
business? Or might low-wage recipients
target high-wage workers for redistributive
taxation?
All kinds of other redistributions
between regions, races and genders display
comparable strategic political choices.
Conflicts over redistributions are thus
intrinsic to capitalism and always have
been. They reflect but also deepen social
divisions. They can and often have become
violent and socially disruptive. They may
trigger demands for system change. They may
function as catalysts for revolutions.
Because pre-capitalist economic systems like
slavery and feudalism had fewer theoretical
and rhetorical commitments to equality in
general, they had fewer redistribution
struggles. Those finally emerged when
inequalities became relatively more extreme
than the levels of inequality that more
frequently provoked redistribution struggles
in capitalism.
No “solution” to divisive struggles over
wealth redistribution in capitalism was ever
found. Capitalisms keep reproducing both
theoretical and rhetorical appeals to
equality as self-celebrations alongside
actualities of deep and deepening wealth
inequalities. Criticisms of capitalism on
grounds of wealth inequality dog the system
everywhere. Divisive social conflicts over
capitalism’s unequal wealth distributions
persist. Endless efforts to find and
implement a successful redistributive system
or mechanism continue. The latest comprises
various proposals for universal basic
incomes.
To avoid divisive social conflict over
redistribution, the solution is not to
distribute unequally in the first place.
That can remove the cause and impetus for
redistributive struggles and thus the need
for endless and so far fruitless efforts to
find the “right” redistribution formula or
mechanism. The way forward is to democratize
the decision about distributing wealth as it
emerges from production. This can be
accomplished by democratizing the
enterprise, converting workplaces from their
current capitalist organization (i.e.,
hierarchical divisions into employers—public
or private—and employees) into worker
cooperatives. In the latter, each worker has
one vote, and all basic workplace issues are
decided by majority vote after a free and
open debate. That is when different views on
what distribution of output should occur are
articulated and democratically decided.
No redistribution is required,
necessitated, or provoked. Workplace members
are free to reopen, debate and decide anew
on initial wealth distributions at any time.
The same procedure would apply to workplace
decisions governing what to produce, which
technology to deploy, and where to locate
production. All workers collectively and
democratically decide what wage the
collective of workers pays to each of them
individually. They likewise decide how to
dispose of or allocate any surplus, which is
above the total individual wage bill and
replacement of used-up inputs, that the
enterprise might generate.
A parable can illustrate the basic point.
Imagine parents taking their twins—Mary and
John—to a park where there is an ice-cream
vendor. The parents buy two ice creams and
give both to Mary. John’s wails provoke a
search for an appropriate redistribution of
ice creams. The parents take away one of the
ice creams from Mary and hand it to John.
Anger, resentment, bitterness, envy and rage
distress the rest of the day and divide
family members. If affection and emotional
support are similarly distributed and
redistributed, deep and divisive scars
result. The lesson: we don’t need a “better”
or “right” redistribution; we need to
distribute more equally and democratically
in the first place.
This article was produced by
Economy for All, a project of the
Independent Media Institute.