Professor Wolff Clearly Explains the
Coming ECONOMIC CRISIS
By Richard Wolff
Richard David Wolff is an American
Marxian economist, well known for his
work on Marxian economics, economic
methodology, and class analysis.
Video Posted March 20, 2017
Questions about Capitalism
Prof. Wolff gives updates on Caterpillar
tax evasion, Obamacare, slave labor for
immigrants, Harvard and slavery,
billionaires, Puerto Rico, and Greece.
Major discussion: questions about
capitalism.
Over the last century, capitalism has
repeatedly revealed its worst
tendencies: instability and inequality.
Instances of instability include the
Great Depression (1929-1941) and the
Great Recession since 2008, plus eleven
"downturns" in the US between those two
global collapses. Each time, millions
lost jobs, misery soared, poverty
worsened and massive resources were
wasted. Leaders promised that their
"reforms" would prevent such instability
from recurring. Those promises were not
kept. Reforms did not work or did not
endure. The system was, and remains, the
problem.
Inequality likewise proved to be an
inherent trend of capitalism. Only
occasionally and temporarily did
opposition from its victims stop or
reverse it. Income and wealth
inequalities have worsened in almost
every capitalist country since at least
the 1970s. Today we have returned to the
huge 19th-century-sized gaps between the
richest 1 percent and everyone else.
Rescuing the "disappearing middle class"
has become every aspiring politician's
slogan. Extreme inequality infects all
of society as corporations and the rich,
to protect their positions, buy the
politicians, mass media and other
cultural forms that are for sale.
Recent Crises in the History of
Capitalism
Capitalism in Western Europe, North
America and Japan -- its original
centers -- has boosted profits in four
basic ways since the 1970s. First, it
computerized and robotized, not to
lessen everyone's work time, but instead
to raise profits by reducing payrolls.
Second, it exploited low-wage immigrant
labor to offset wage increases won by
years of labor struggles. Third, it
moved production to lower-wage countries
such as China, India, Brazil and others.
Fourth, it divided and weakened the
labor unions, political party groups and
other organizations that pursued labor's
interests. As a result, inside nearly
every country of the global capitalist
system, the rich-poor divide deepened.
The Great Depression provoked economic
"reforms," such as FDR's New Deal. These
included regulations restricting risky
bank and other market practices.
Reforming governments also established
public pensions, unemployment insurance,
public employment systems, minimum
wages, monetary and fiscal policies, and
so on. Advocates believed that such
reforms would end the 1930s depression
and prevent future depressions. They
dismissed critics who diagnosed
depressions as systemic and prescribed
system change (or "revolution") as the
necessary solution. "Reform versus
revolution" was then a hot debate.
In
the US, the reformers defeated the
revolutionaries as preparation for war
-- and then war itself -- finally ended
the Great Depression. As capitalism
rebounded after 1945, capitalists
increasingly evaded the Depression-era
reforms, using their growing wealth to
buy the political influence needed to
gut many reforms. Later, Reagan led the
frontal assault, repackaged as
"globalization" and "neoliberalism" to
undo the New Deal. When that rollback of
reforms culminated in the 2008 crash, it
exposed capitalism's instability and
inequality yet again.
The continuing post-2008 economic crisis
has reproduced both the kinds of
suffering that happened after 1929 and
the reform-versus-revolution debates.
The difference this time is that we know
what happened last time. While the
reformers then defeated the
revolutionaries, their reforms failed to
prevent the continuation of capitalism's
instability and inequality, and their
harmful social effects. Reformism today
advocates the same (or a slightly
varied) set of reforms as last time. It
thus represents a refusal to learn from
our history. The revolutionary
alternative now makes more sense.
"Revolutionary," however, need not evoke
romantic notions of storming barricades:
Today, revolutionary refers to the
recognition that system change, not
another reform, is our primary task.
What System Change Requires
What differentiates system change from
reforms? Reforms refer to government
interventions that still leave employers
in the exclusive position to make the
basic enterprise decisions: what, how
and where to produce and what to do with
profits. Reforms include minimum wage
laws, redistributive tax structures, and
enterprises owned and operated by the
government. They range from the mildly
Keynesian (the New Deal) to the
democratic socialist (what we see in
Scandinavian countries) to the state
socialist (the model of the USSR and
People's Republic of China). All such
reforms retain the core relationship
inside enterprises as that of
employer-employee, with private or
public directors controlling the mass of
workers and making the basic enterprise
decisions.
No
Advertising - No Government Grants - This Is Independent Media
In
contrast, system change means
reorganizing the core human relationship
inside the factories, offices and stores
of an economy. That relationship
connects all who participate in
production and distribution of goods and
services. It shapes (1) who produces
what, how and where; (2) how much
surplus or profits are available; and
(3) the disposition of the surplus or
profits.
Truly moving beyond capitalism means
breaking from the employer-employee core
relationship. It means no longer
assigning a relatively tiny number of
people inside each enterprise to the
employer position of exclusively making
the sorts of decisions outlined above.
In private corporations the employers
are the boards of directors selected by
the major shareholders. In state or
public enterprises of the traditional
socialist economies, the employers are
state officials. Instead of either kind
of employer-employee relationship,
system change installs a different core
relationship inside enterprises. A
different group of people -- all workers
in the factory, office or store --
democratically makes those same
decisions. The rule is "one worker, one
vote," and in general, the majority
decides. The difference between employer
and employee dissolves.
Such system change beyond capitalism
means something quite different from
shifting to public directors from
private directors, which is a reform.
System change entails the
democratization of the workplace. The
logic governing the economic system,
then, would no longer be capital-centric
(making decisions (1) through (3) in
such a particular way that the
capitalist employer-employee
relationship in production is
reproduced). The particular connecting
relationship at the core of capitalism
will have been superseded: rather like
what happened earlier to the
slave-centric core relationship
(master-slave) and the feudal-centric
core relationship (lord-serf). Instead,
the post-capitalist core relationship
will be democratically worker-centric,
with the central type of workplace being
the worker cooperative.
Among the goals driving an economy based
on democratic worker coops, job
security, quality of workers' lives and
reproduction of the worker coop core
relationship in production will weigh
more heavily than enterprise profits.
Because different people will be making
the key enterprise decisions and because
those people will be driven by different
goals, the post-capitalist society will
develop very differently from the
capitalist. Democratic worker coops will
likely (1) not relocate themselves
overseas, (2) distribute incomes far
less unequally than capitalist
enterprise, (3) not install ecologically
damaging technologies near where their
families and neighbors reside, and so
on.
Responding to reductions in demands for
their outputs, worker coops will more
likely stress sharing any reduced work
hours among all workers rather than
forcing a few into unemployment. The
needless social irrationality of
capitalist downturns -- when unemployed
workers coexist with unutilized means of
production to leave social needs unmet
-- will be much more apparent and thus
widely unacceptable.
In
an economy built on worker coops,
children, retired people, people living
with disabilities or illness and others
outside the labor force would be
sustained from the worker coops'
"surplus." The latter comprises what the
coop labor force produces above and
beyond what it consumes and requires to
replace used-up means of production.
Adults in and out of the coop labor
force would together and democratically
determine the sizes and recipients of
all the distributions of the surplus.
They would decide how much of the
surplus would go to expanding
production, to provisions for future
contingencies, to providing for
children, for those in other social
institutions, and so on. In place of
capitalists (a social minority)
distributing the surpluses produced by
and appropriated from their employees, a
genuine democracy would govern that
distribution, much as it governs other
worker coop decisions.
Worker coops mark a qualitative and
quantitative advance beyond capitalism.
They represent a system change adequate
to key problems capitalism has shown it
cannot overcome, even after centuries of
failed efforts to do so.
The
views expressed in this article are solely those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect the opinions of Information Clearing
House.
It is unacceptable to slander, smear or engage in personal attacks on authors of articles posted on ICH.
Those engaging in that behavior will be banned from the comment section.
In accordance
with Title 17 U.S.C. Section 107, this material
is distributed without profit to those who have
expressed a prior interest in receiving the
included information for research and educational
purposes. Information Clearing House has no
affiliation whatsoever with the originator of
this article nor is Information ClearingHouse
endorsed or sponsored by the originator.)